[House Hearing, 113 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] BANKRUPTCY CODE AND FINANCIAL INSTITUTION INSOLVENCIES ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON REGULATORY REFORM, COMMERCIAL AND ANTITRUST LAW OF THE COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED THIRTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ DECEMBER 3, 2013 __________ Serial No. 113-59 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on the Judiciary Available via the World Wide Web: http://judiciary.house.gov ---------- U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 85-763 PDF WASHINGTON : 2014 ----------------------------------------------------------------------- For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 COMMITTEE ON THE JUDICIARY BOB GOODLATTE, Virginia, Chairman F. JAMES SENSENBRENNER, Jr., JOHN CONYERS, Jr., Michigan Wisconsin JERROLD NADLER, New York HOWARD COBLE, North Carolina ROBERT C. ``BOBBY'' SCOTT, LAMAR SMITH, Texas Virginia STEVE CHABOT, Ohio MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama ZOE LOFGREN, California DARRELL E. ISSA, California SHEILA JACKSON LEE, Texas J. RANDY FORBES, Virginia STEVE COHEN, Tennessee STEVE KING, Iowa HENRY C. ``HANK'' JOHNSON, Jr., TRENT FRANKS, Arizona Georgia LOUIE GOHMERT, Texas PEDRO R. PIERLUISI, Puerto Rico JIM JORDAN, Ohio JUDY CHU, California TED POE, Texas TED DEUTCH, Florida JASON CHAFFETZ, Utah LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois TOM MARINO, Pennsylvania KAREN BASS, California TREY GOWDY, South Carolina CEDRIC RICHMOND, Louisiana MARK AMODEI, Nevada SUZAN DelBENE, Washington RAUL LABRADOR, Idaho JOE GARCIA, Florida BLAKE FARENTHOLD, Texas HAKEEM JEFFRIES, New York GEORGE HOLDING, North Carolina DOUG COLLINS, Georgia RON DeSANTIS, FLORIDA JASON T. SMITH, Missouri Shelley Husband, Chief of Staff & General Counsel Perry Apelbaum, Minority Staff Director & Chief Counsel ------ Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama, Chairman BLAKE FARENTHOLD, Texas, Vice-Chairman DARRELL E. ISSA, California STEVE COHEN, Tennessee TOM MARINO, Pennsylvania HENRY C. ``HANK'' JOHNSON, Jr., GEORGE HOLDING, North Carolina Georgia DOUG COLLINS, Georgia SUZAN DelBENE, Washington JASON T. SMITH, Missouri JOE GARCIA, Florida HAKEEM JEFFRIES, New York Daniel Flores, Chief Counsel James Park, Minority Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- DECEMBER 3, 2013 Page OPENING STATEMENTS The Honorable Spencer Bachus, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law........................... 1 The Honorable Steve Cohen, a Representative in Congress from the State of Tennessee, and Ranking Member, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law................ 6 The Honorable Bob Goodlatte, a Representative in Congress from the State of Virginia, and Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary 8 WITNESSES Jeffrey M. Lacker, President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Oral Testimony................................................. 10 Prepared Statement............................................. 13 Donald S. Bernstein, Co-Chair, Insolvency and Restructuring Group, Davis Polk and Wardell L.L.P. Oral Testimony................................................. 67 Prepared Statement............................................. 72 Mark J. Roe, Professor of Law, Harvard Law School Oral Testimony................................................. 91 Prepared Statement............................................. 94 LETTERS, STATEMENTS, ETC., SUBMITTED FOR THE HEARING Material submitted by the Honorable Spencer Bachus, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law.................................................. 2 APPENDIX Material Submitted for the Hearing Record Prepared Statement of the Honorable Spencer Bachus, a Representative in Congress from the State of Alabama, and Chairman, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law.................................................. 116 Prepared Statement of the Honorable Steve Cohen, a Representative in Congress from the State of Tennessee, and Ranking Member, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law 119 Prepared Statement of the Honorable Bob Goodlatte, a Representative in Congress from the State of Virginia, and Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary........................... 119 Prepared Statement of the Honorable John Conyers, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Michigan, and Ranking Member, Committee on the Judiciary..................... 120 Response to Questions for the Record from Jeffrey M. Lacker, President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.................... 121 Response to Questions for the Record from Mark J. Roe, Professor of Law, Harvard Law School..................................... 123 BANKRUPTCY CODE AND FINANCIAL INSTITUTION INSOLVENCIES ---------- TUESDAY, DECEMBER 3, 2013 House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law Committee on the Judiciary, Washington, DC. The Subcommittee met, pursuant to call, at 1:54 p.m., in room 2141, Rayburn Office Building, the Honorable Spencer Bachus (Chairman of the Subcommittee) presiding. Present: Representatives Bachus, Goodlatte, Marino, Holding, Collins, Smith of Missouri, Cohen, DelBene, and Garcia. Staff present: (Majority) Anthony Grossi, Counsel; Ashley Lewis, Clerk; and (Minority) James Park, Minority Counsel. Mr. Bachus. Well, good afternoon. The Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law hearing will come to order. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare recesses of the Committee at any time. And, if we have votes, we will recess for those votes. Now, I will recognize myself for an opening statement. I would like to enter into the record the Committee memo that was prepared for this hearing. In my view, it is an excellent overview of the issues involved with improving the Bankruptcy Code in its role as a primary mechanism for dealing with distressed or insolvent financial institutions. [The information referred to follows:] [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Bachus. One of our witnesses today is the president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Jeffrey Lacker. And let me say that there are statistics in an essay prepared by the Richmond Fed that underscore the importance of what we are talking about. And let me read from the essay directly. And I quote, this was I think 2011 essay and it was on ``too big to fail.'' According to--and I quote, ``according to Richmond Fed estimates, the proportion of total U.S. financial firms liabilities covered by the Federal financial safety net has increased by 27 percent during the past 12 years. The safety net covered $25 trillion in liabilities at the end of 2011 or 57.1 percent of the entire financial sector. Nearly two thirds of the support is implicit and ambiguous.'' And I think you see that two-thirds portion when we talk about Lehman and Bear Stearns. Where Bear Stearns received financial support from the government several months later. People are thinking, maybe that it is implied, that they will do the same thing with Lehman. And it didn't happen. And one of the results was people didn't prepare for it. It surprised people. And the uncertainty that ensuring--the government, the taxpayer ensuring that large portion of the financial assets of our country, the great majority, and then two thirds of that support being iffy is, I think, is a condition that all of us, in a bipartisan way, ought to be concerned about. Those are very significant financial liabilities to place on the Federal Government and ultimately on taxpayers. It is a structure that can tilt the field toward government intervention and bailouts. In my view, statistics like this strengthen the case for improving the bankruptcy process so that risks are borne by private parties and cases are handled in a consistent way, based on established precedent and rule of law. And let me say, this hearing is not about Dodd-Frank. But Dodd-Frank actually set up the mechanism for utilization of bankruptcy. So this hearing is not an attempt to substitute something for Dodd-Frank. In fact, Dodd-Frank called for a GAO hearing and Fed studies on how to improve bankruptcy. So, nothing we are saying today is an indictment of Dodd-Frank. In fact, ``living wills'' have been one of the few things that I think almost everyone, in a bipartisan way, has said that was a good thing. Although there is a--we discussed earlier witnesses, you have to be cautious that you don't set up a corporation structure as if it is going to bankrupt. But you ought to--there ought to be planning of what you are going to do in the case there is a bankruptcy. With that, let me recognize the Ranking Member of the Subcommittee, Mr. Cohen of Tennessee, for his opening statement. Mr. Cohen. Thank you, Mr. Chair. And I couldn't not start this hearing without congratulating you on your Auburn victory. What an unbelievable game. And you were there. I would like to yield to you. Would you tell us--we heard what the Auburn announcer said, when the kick was returned. Can you tell us what you said as the kick was returned? [Laughter.] Mr. Collins. The Alabama perspective was, ``Oh, God.'' Mr. Cohen. And the Auburn perspective was, ``Thank God?'' [Laughter.] Mr. Bachus. Well, you know, I am--having represented Tuscaloosa County, the home of the University of Alabama for 20 years, I am not all that vocal sometimes. But, I was thinking how lucky Auburn had been two games in a row. And I thought that after that immaculate catch against Georgia that we had had all the luck we deserved. But, we got some more of it. It was something to see. Mr. Cohen. But, what did you say? Did you say anything at all? I mean---- Mr. Bachus. No. I sort of had that expression, if you seen number 56, that freshman at Auburn that has been on ESPN where---- [Laughter.] He is trying to put this all together. That's what we did. My wife is a University of Alabama graduate too. So---- Mr. Cohen. That was a smart move on your part. Mr. Bachus. So, I was telling her how sorry I was. But she knew I wasn't very sincere. [Laughter.] Mr. Cohen. You are the kind of the opposite of McKaren and his girlfriend. Mr. Bachus. Yeah, she is an Auburn brat. Mr. Cohen. I know it. Mr. Bachus. That is how it is going to be. [Laughter.] All right. Mr. Cohen. Did you go to Toomer's Corner and throw toilet paper? Mr. Bachus. No. You know what, an Alabama fan poisoned those trees and killed them. That is true, I don't know if you knew that. Mr. Cohen. They pled guilty and should have gone to jail for a long time. Mr. Bachus. Yeah. Mr. Cohen. Bad guy. Mr. Bachus. But the---- [Laughter.] That is actually--that is true he went--but, you know, he was responding to Auburn students putting an--after the 2010 victory over Alabama, Cam Newton, they put an Auburn jacket on Bear Bryant's statute. So, he felt like that was---- Mr. Cohen. That was disrespectful. Mr. Bachus. Yes. Mr. Cohen. But, not worthy of killing trees. Mr. Bachus. No, they didn't kill Bear Bryant's statue. Mr. Cohen. Innocent there. Mr. Bachus. All right. I am sorry. Mr. Cohen. Back to Dodd-Frank---- [Laughter.] Which I voted for and proudly then, and support to this day and continue to. Its passage by Congress in 2010 was an acknowledgment that insufficient regulation led to the problem of the so-called ``too big to fail'' financial institutions. Those were institutions that became so big and so interconnected that their insolvencies threatened to paralyze the entire financial system and the economy of the world. This situation in turn resulted in extreme pressure for taxpayer bailouts when those institutions fell under financial stress. And the bill, I think, was somewhat bipartisan, pretty bipartisan to save the country and bail out the banks because we had to. The bankruptcy filing of Lehman Brothers in 2008, which was the largest bankruptcy in our history, involved more than $600 billion in assets and illustrates this problem. The bankruptcy filing greatly exacerbated the financial panic on Wall Street, leading to a severe crisis in the greatest economic downturn since the Great Depression, now we call it the Great Recession. The financial markets' reaction to Lehman Brothers' bankruptcy highlighted potential limitations of the Bankruptcy Code in handling the resolution of these financially distressed institutions and the systemic effect they would have on financial institutions in general. Dodd-Frank has certain enhancements in it that are strong ways that we have dealt with and responded to that problem. I support legislation to increase the minimum required amount of capital for covered financial institutions under Dodd-Frank. We should also consider the potential need for other enhancements like adding a representative of the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice to the Financial Stability Oversight Council, which was created by Dodd-Frank to oversee the stability of the financial system. It is in this spirit that I approach today's hearing, which will focus on whether current Bankruptcy Code is sufficient to allow for the early reorganization or liquidation of systemically important financial institutions under title I of Dodd-Frank. Whether one supports or doesn't support Dodd-Frank, we can agree that today's inquiry is an important one to the extent that modest revisions to the Bankruptcy Code will help ensure that we avoid the need for additional future taxpayer bailouts of financially struggling large financial institutions. We should be able to work together in crafting such changes. Just as the Chairman of the full Committee brought us together on patent reform, I feel confident that the Chairman of the Subcommittee, that great Auburn war eagle, can bring us together on something to solve this problem too. With that, I yield back the balance of my time. Mr. Bachus. I thank Mr. Cohen for that opening statement. And, at this time, I recognize Chairman Goodlatte, the full Committee Chairman. Mr. Goodlatte. Well, thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate your holding this hearing. The Bankruptcy Code has existed in this country for well over a hundred years. Over this time, our bankruptcy system has evolved to become one of the most sophisticated regimes in the world. The bedrock principle embedded in the bankruptcy system of providing for the efficient resolution and reorganization of operating firms, has allowed our economy to grow and flourish. Nevertheless, a periodic evaluation of the Bankruptcy Code to ensure its adequacy to address the challenges posed by the changing nature of operating firms, is one of the fundamental responsibilities of this Committee. I applaud Chairman Bachus for holding today's hearing to examine whether the existing Bankruptcy Code is best equipped to address the insolvency of large and small financial institutions. The bankruptcy process confers a number of benefits to all operating companies, including financial firms. The bankruptcy court provides transparency and due process to all parties involved. Furthermore, bankruptcy case law has been developed over decades providing consistency and predictability. Additionally, the bankruptcy process has been sufficiently dynamic to administer the resolution and restructuring of complex operating companies with billions of dollars in assets, as well as smaller companies and individuals. But, despite the bankruptcy system's ability to accommodate complex operating companies, financial firms may possess unique characteristics that are not yet optimally accounted for in the Bankruptcy Code. For example, efficient and orderly resolution of financial firms can require an unusual level of speed. Refinements to the code might be considered to provide--to better provide that speed, while still assuring due process. Additionally, in some circumstances, the failure of financial firms can pose unique threats to the broader stability of the economy. To account for that, title I of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act requires certain firms to prepare ``living wills'' to plan for resolution in bankruptcy in the event of failure. The Bankruptcy Code is well crafted to maximize the recoveries of a debtor's creditors, while providing an opportunity for the debtor to either reorganize or liquidate in an orderly fashion. It might, however, bear improvements designed specifically for the efficient execution of title I living wills. There are some of the--these are some of the issues that may need to be examined as part of the broader evaluation of the existing Bankruptcy Code's adequacy to address financial institution insolvencies. I look forward to the testimony from today's excellent panel of witnesses on these important issues. And, Mr. Chairman, I thank you and yield back the balance of my time. Mr. Bachus. I thank you. And without objection, other Members' opening statements will be made a part of the record. And I do agree with the Chairman when he says that we have an excellent panel of witnesses, because we do have three of-- really people that, in a bipartisan nature, we consider experts on bankruptcy and how it can be enhanced to address complex situations. I will first begin by introducing our witnesses. Governor Lacker is the current president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, where he began his term on August 1st, 2004. Prior to serving as the president of the Richmond Federal Reserve, he was a research economist with the bank for 25 years, serving in various capacities including vice president, senior vice president and director of research. He is the author of numerous articles and professional journals on monetary financial and payment economics. And he has presented his work at universities and central banks worldwide. He received his BA in economics from Franklin and Marshall College, and a doctorate in economics from the University of Wisconsin. Mr. Bernstein, Donald Bernstein, is a partner of Davis Polk here in Washington. Is that right or New York? New York, okay. Where he heads the firm's insolvency and restructuring practice. During his distinguished 35-year career, he has represented nearly every major financial institution in numerous restructuring, as well as leading a number of operating firms through bankruptcy including Ford, LTV Steel, and Johns Manville. Mr. Bernstein has earned multiple honors for his practice including being elected by his peers as the chair of the National Bankruptcy Conference, the most prestigious professional organization in the field of bankruptcy. Mr. Bernstein received his AB cum laude from Princeton University and his JD from the University of Chicago Law School. And we welcome you. Professor Mark Roe is a professor of law at Harvard Law School where he teaches business bankruptcy and corporations courses. Professor Roe has authored countless articles and opinion pieces that have been published across the globe including in the law reviews and--the law reviews of Penn, Virginia, Columbia, Michigan, Stanford, Yale, and Harvard. He also literally wrote the book on corporate restructuring that is used in law schools across the country. Prior to joining Harvard's faculty, Professor Roe taught law at Columbia University, the University of Pennsylvania and Rutgers University. Prior to joining academia, he worked at the law firm of Cahill Gordon and at the Federal Reserve. Professor Roe received his BA from Columbia University summa cum laude, and his JD from Harvard Law School. Each of the witnesses' written statements will be entered into the record in its entirety. I ask that each of the witnesses summarize his testimony or her testimony. I am not going to restrict you to 5 minutes, I think it is too important. If you go over that, that is fine. And so I am not going to read this about the light and all that. So, we--at this time, Governor Lacker, you are recognized for your opening statement. TESTIMONY OF JEFFREY M. LACKER, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND Mr. Lacker. Thank you, good morning. I am honored to speak to the Subcommittee about why I believe it is important to improve our Bankruptcy Code to make it easier to resolve failing financial firms in bankruptcy. At the outset I should say that my comments reflect my own views and do not necessarily reflect those of the Board of Governors or my other colleagues at other Federal Reserve banks. I think the events of 2008 provide strong evidence of glaring deficiencies in the way financial institution distress and insolvency are handled, particularly at large institutions. The problem, widely known as ``too big to fail,'' consists of two mutually reinforcing expectations. First, many financial institution creditors feel protected by an implicit government commitment of support should the institution face financial distress. This belief dampens creditors' attention to risk and it leads to overuse of types of borrowing such as short-term wholesale funding that are more fragile, more prone to runs, more prone to volatility. The second of these two mutually reinforcing expectations is that if a large financial firm is highly dependent on short- term funding, policymakers are often unwilling to let it file for bankruptcy under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code fearing that it would result in undesirable effects on counterparties. This fear leads policymakers to intervene in ways that allow short- term creditors to escape losses such as through central bank lending or public sector capital injections. This behavior just reinforces creditors' expectations of support. That in turn reinforces firms' incentives to grow large and their incentive to rely on short-term funding which in turn reinforces policymakers' proclivity for intervening to support creditors. The result is more financial fragility and more rescues. The path toward a stable financial system requires that policymakers have confidence in the unassisted failure of financial firms under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code and that investors are thereby convinced that unassisted bankruptcy is the norm. This is why I believe it is vitally important to ensure that our bankruptcy laws are well crafted to apply to large financial institutions. In response to the experience of 2008, title I of the Dodd- Frank Act laid out a planning process for the resolution of failed financial institutions. A resolution plan or ``living will,'' as they are popularly called, is the description of a firm's strategy for rapid and orderly resolution under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code without government assistance. It spells out the firm's organizational structure, key management information systems, critical operations, and a mapping of the relationship between core business lines and legal entities. The heart of the plan is the specification of the actions the firm would take to facilitate rapid and orderly resolution and prevent adverse effects of failure, especially the firm's strategy to maintain critical operations and funding. The Federal Reserve and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation can jointly determine that a plan is ``not credible'' or would not facilitate the orderly resolution--an orderly resolution under the Bankruptcy Code. And, in that case, the firm would be required to submit a revised plan to address deficiencies. If the Fed and the FDIC jointly determine that the revised plan does not remedy identified deficiencies, they can require more capital, increase liquidity requirements, reduce reliance on short-term funding, or restrict the growth, activities or operations of the firm. In essence, regulators can order changes in the structure and operations of a firm to make it resolvable in bankruptcy without government assistance. Note the implication here that if a firm would require, the way it is running itself now, an unrealistically large amount of ``debtor-in-possession'' financing, regulators can require ex ante, pre-bankruptcy changes in the firm's funding structure so that plans for funding operations in bankruptcy are realistic and credible. Title II of the Dodd-Frank Act gives the FDIC the ability to take a firm into receivership under its so-called ``Orderly Liquidation Authority,'' if there is a determination that the firm's failure under the U.S. Bankruptcy Code would have serious adverse effects on U.S. financial stability. Title II receivership differs from the Bankruptcy Code in that the FDIC would have the ability to borrow funds from the U.S. Treasury to support creditors, and would have broad discretion to treat similarly situated creditors differently. This is likely to replicate the two mutually reinforcing expectations that define ``too big to fail.'' And this is why improving the Bankruptcy Code to facilitate orderly resolution of large financial firms is so important. It would position us to wind down the Orderly Liquidation Authority at an appropriate time and to wind down other financing mechanisms such as the Federal Reserves' remaining 13(3) powers to lend in ``unusual and exigent circumstances.'' Without winding these down, I think that those mutually reinforcing conditions are likely to arise again. Expectations of support, in the absence of clear guidance as to when and where support will be forthcoming, will encourage excessive risk taking. That risk taking will trap policymakers. It will put them in a box and force them to respond with rescues and support, in the event of distress. The Dodd-Frank Act itself clearly envisions bankruptcy without government support as the first and most preferable option in the case of a failing financial institution, and for good reason, in my view. The expectation of resolution in bankruptcy without government support would result in a much better alignment between the incentives of market participants and our public policy goal of a financial system that effectively allocates capital and risk. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Mr. Lacker follows:] [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Bachus. Thank you. Mr. Bernstein? TESTIMONY OF DONALD S. BERNSTEIN, CO-CHAIR, INSOLVENCY AND RESTRUCTURING GROUP, DAVIS POLK AND WARDELL L.L.P. Mr. Bernstein. Well, thank you for inviting me to testify. I have spent a lot of my practice life dealing with the failures of financial institutions, starting with Drexel Burnham many years ago. And, in recent years, I have done a lot of work on resolution plans, ``living wills.'' I too am here in my individual capacity, however, and the views I express are my own. They are not to be attributed to my firm or clients or organizations with which I am affiliated. I want to begin with a few observations about the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy and its implications for the bankruptcy of other large financial institutions. Then I am going to provide a bit of an overview of how orderly liquidation authority is being contemplated to be used, including the single point of entry resolution strategy that has been developed by the FDIC. And then, I am going to turn to the Bankruptcy Code and talk a bit about how resolution planning has interfaced with the Bankruptcy Code in its current form. And I will end with a few suggestions as to the way the code might be amended to make it easier to resolve financial firms. The unplanned failure of Lehman Brothers as we all know had an enormously disruptive effect on the U.S. economy. Financial firms are very vulnerable to a loss of confidence. Even if their economic fundamentals haven't changed once the confidence is lost because they are in the business of so-called maturity transformation. They incur short-term liabilities like deposits and some of the other short-term liabilities that were just mentioned and they invest them in long-term assets like mortgages and corporate loans and the like. And when short-term creditors lose confidence they run. They take their money and they run. And if a run is prolonged and intense, it can force the firm to sell assets at fire-sale prices and distress markets and exacerbate any losses that might otherwise exist. And that also results in depressing market values generally, which has a follow-on effect to other firms. So, if you have this process of unwinding of maturity transformation from what it has been called, ``contagious panic,'' you end up with a very destabilizing situation. And, in fact, that is how Lehman Brothers' unplanned failure actually unfolded. Now, to avoid this disrupt--this abrupt unraveling of maturity transformation, distressed firms need to be able to meet sudden liquidity needs without being forced to abruptly sell their assets. And, over the longer term, they need to be able to either be recapitalized or wound down in an orderly way that doesn't create the risk of fire sales of assets. In 2008, neither the regulators nor the firms had the tools to accomplish these goals without financial support from taxpayers. And though the large institutions ended up repaying those investments, there was wide recognition that more tools were needed to avoid having taxpayer funds put at risk again. Many regulators and commentators believe that some of the tools that are being developed, under title II of Dodd-Frank, actually accomplish this goal. And I am going to describe the single point of entry tool, which is the most--the one that is most frequently discussed. In a single point of entry resolution, only the holding company for the financial institution is put into an insolvency or receivership proceeding. All of the losses are borne by the holding companies, creditors and shareholders. And the operating subsidiaries, like the bank or the broker-dealer, wouldn't fail. They would be recapitalized using assets that are maintained for that purpose at the holding company and they would continue in business as a newly created--as subsidiaries of a newly created holding company which, under orderly liquidation authority, is called a bridge holding company. There are a number of reasons why many people think this approach has some viability. The first is that the holding company structure used by large financial institutions creates an additional layer of loss-absorbing debt that is effectively subordinated to operating liabilities and especially the short- term liabilities that were just mentioned that are down in the operating subsidiaries. The firms have also substantially increased the amount of loss-absorbing capital and debt that are in the holding companies and new rules are expected to be forthcoming that require them to maintain sufficient loss- absorbing debt and assets at their holding companies. So financially the firms should be in a position to execute the type of recapitalization that is being contemplated with all of this additional loss absorbency that they have. In addition, because the firm's operating subsidiaries keep in business, single point of entry eliminates the need for multiple insolvency proceedings for different entities, both domestically and in foreign countries, which greatly reduces the complexity of the resolution process. That was one of the big problems in Lehman Brothers. You had a siloing of each entity, one from the other, that resulted in the inability to effectively resolve because you had too many people, too many parties to consult with and the inability to deal with entities on a regular-way basis. To supplement this, there have been initiatives on a multinational level including those at the Financial Stability Board and crisis management groups that have been organized by key regulators of individual firms that are creating increased alignment among the national regulatory authorities regarding the benefits of what are called single point of entry and bail- in approaches to the failure of financial firms. And this is evidenced by joint work that has been done by the FDIC and the Bank of England on the subject. Finally and importantly, orderly liquidation authority does include certain special tools that are not currently available under the Bankruptcy Code. And that is going to lead me into my discussion of bankruptcy. But, those tools really are not that--there aren't that many of them. There are three very important ones. One is the clear path that orderly liquidation authority provides to creating a bridge holding company and transferring the stock of recapitalized subsidiaries to the bridge holding company. That separates them from the debt and the equity of the old holding company and effectively creates a recapitalized entity. The second important feature is the orderly liquidation fund which is underwritten by the private sector and provides fully secured interim liquidity, if needed, to stabilize the recapitalized firm. And the third is the preservation of financial contracts by briefly staying closeouts and having provisions that override cross-defaults and bankruptcy defaults so the contracts can be assumed by the ongoing entities. Again, a problem that was faced in Lehman Brothers because of the safe harbors in the Bankruptcy Code. Recognizing that progress is being made in developing the single point of entry strategy, just a couple of weeks ago, Moody's Investor Service announced that it was removing the two notch uplift provided to ratings of debt of the largest bank holding companies to account for the possibility of government support. Effectively, they have reached the conclusion that that government support is going to be unnecessary because of the progress that is being made on resolution. So, let us turn to the Bankruptcy Code now. I agree completely that traditional bankruptcy proceedings do provide a path that, despite the Lehman Brothers' experience, can be utilized to resolve financial firms provided that there is appropriate preplanning. The Bankruptcy Code provides transparency. It provides the opportunity for effected parties to receive notice and be heard in court and ex ante judicial review prior to major actions. All of which serve to inspire market confidence. And, if you talk to people who are investors, all of them like--uniformly like the Bankruptcy Code. They like the transparency. In my view, these are clear benefits of the bankruptcy process. However, the absence of the special tools available under orderly liquidation authority makes it harder for financial firms in bankruptcy to utilize a single point of entry strategy. As a result, the title resolution--title I resolution plans typically adopt a hybrid approach in which some operating businesses are contemplated to be sold or recapitalized, while others are allowed to wind down in an orderly way. First, the resolution plans identify the material operating entities that, because of their capital structure or the nature of their business, are unlikely either to suffer losses or that can be recapitalized as they would be under orderly liquidation authority. And then, there are tools, such as Section 363 of the Bankruptcy Code that can be used to accomplish a speedy sale or transfer of the stock of those entities that are not going to fail to a debt-free holding company or to a third party. And the debt-free holding company might be owned by a trust for the creditors of the bankruptcy estate so that the creditors in fact are not losing value, but they are actually preserving the going concern value and it is being held for their benefit by a fiduciary. The new holding company can then be sold in private transactions or public transactions, pieces of it can be sold or its shares can be distributed to the left-behind creditors in a conventional Chapter 11 plan of reorganization. This is all possible under the current code. Now, entities that can't be sold or recapitalized need to be wound down in an orderly way. And the wind downs need to be carefully planned taking into account the impact of the different insolvency regimes; the reactions of regulators, customers, counterparties, financial market utilities, and others that need to be anticipated in the resolution plan. Liquidity needs, through the wind down, need to be conservatively anticipated and the maintenance of shared services and technology, and the transition of critical operations to other firms, and the distribution of customer assets and property need to be provided for. Today, liquidity levels at the firms allow them to sustain in addition a pre-failure runoff of some of their balance sheet. You may recall that in 2008 one of the problems that faced Lehman Brothers was---- Mr. Bachus. Let me---- Mr. Bernstein. Sorry. Mr. Bachus. We have a pending vote series---- Mr. Bernstein. Okay. Mr. Bachus [continuing]. On the House floor. So, we are going to stand in recess. We will come back and I will allow Mr. Bernstein to complete that very good opening statement. And the Committee stands in recess, subject to the call of the Chair. And we ask Members to return immediately so we may resume the hearing as soon as possible. And we anticipate doing that fairly soon, but the staff will keep you abreast. Thank you. [Recess.] Mr. Bachus. We will go ahead and commence the hearing so that the Committee is called to order. And, Mr. Bernstein, you are recognized for your---- Mr. Bernstein. Thank you, Mr. Chair. So, I was just describing how the resolution plans seem to be evolving into hybrid strategies involving continuation of some entities and wind down of others. And I was giving an example of how today, with the liquidity levels that the firms have, some of that wind down can actually happen prior to failure because they have got the ability to address liabilities that are running for a period of time because of the liquidity on their balance sheets. And I was mentioning the example of prime brokerage accounts, which were one of the precipitating liquidity factors in Lehman's bankruptcy. And that is something that can be planned for. And it can actually make the resolution process less complex and less systemically disruptive. And I also note in my written statement a number of other ways that the plans contemplate taking steps, either well in advance or immediately prior to the failure of the firm, to reduce the complexity of the wind downs of entities that are not being recapitalized or sold. So, to summarize, the title I plans rely on a combination of approaches to orderly resolution under the code. They adjust some current operating practices to simplify resolution. They plan for client-driven reductions in the firm's balance sheet, prior to resolution. They preplan the marketing and sale of some of the firm's businesses. They contemplate recapitalization and continuation of others and the wind down of still others. Those hybrid approaches can actually be quite robust with appropriately detailed planning. And I can't emphasize that enough. The plans are extremely detailed and they need to be. So, part of making these things work is not only the planning process, but also appropriate consultation with regulators in advance and education of both regulators, market participants and those who administer the bankruptcy process so they understand how these plans work and are in a better position to implement them. Now all of that being said, I think the hybrid approaches do entail complexity and more risk than the single point of entry approach. So, I believe that reforms to the Bankruptcy Code that add tools to facilitate the single point of entry approach, perhaps in the form of a modified Chapter 14, which I know people have been talking about, should be considered. These changes would include, among other things, clarifying that bank holding companies can indeed recapitalize their operating subsidiaries prior to commencement of bankruptcy proceedings; clarifying that Section 363 of the Bankruptcy Code can be used to create a new bridge holding company, in the manner that I described; briefly staying closeouts and allowing the assumption and preservation of financial contracts, including overriding bankruptcy defaults or cross defaults to facilitate resolution; and providing a fully secured resource, like the OLF, to be available if DIP financing, debtor-in- possession financing, is not available in the market. Expanding resolution options in bankruptcy will minimize systemic risk and better avoid putting taxpayer money at risk. But, importantly, even if the Bankruptcy Code is amended, I think it is important that we retain all of our options. That single point of entry in bankruptcy is not the only option, but that the orderly liquidation authority be retained as a backup option; not necessarily the first choice, but just to have it there in case it is needed. We can't know what the contours of the next crisis will be. And we should want regulators to have the greatest variety of tools in their toolkit. In addition, host country regulators, regulators in other countries who are less familiar with our bankruptcy system, will take comfort from the fact that, if all else fails, U.S. regulators have the power to act. I want to thank you for allowing me this opportunity to present my views. [The prepared statement of Mr. Bernstein follows:] [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Bachus. Thank you very much. And, Professor Roe? Now, let me say this, I think that the testimony so far has been very substantial and very helpful. And it--a lot of good discussion on policy. So, thank you. TESTIMONY OF MARK J. ROE, PROFESSOR OF LAW, HARVARD LAW SCHOOL Mr. Roe. I will do my best to maintain that. So, Chairman Bachus, thank you for the gracious introduction earlier. I am Mark Roe. I am a law professor who focuses on corporate law, business law, business bankruptcy issues. And I do appreciate the opportunity to be here to provide you with my views on the Bankruptcy Code's adequacy in dealing with failing, failed financial institutions. I am going to focus my testimony on the exemptions from bankruptcy for derivatives and short-term financing, the so- called ``bankruptcy safe harbors.'' Simply put, the Bankruptcy Code, as it is set up now, cannot effectively deal with most large failing financial institutions. And a core reason for that is that the safe harbors are far too wide. They exempt too much short-term financing and risky investments from the normal operation of American bankruptcy law. They thereby make an effective resolution in bankruptcy without regulatory support harder than it needs to be, quite possibly impossible. They undermine market discipline in the prebankruptcy market making the financial system riskier and more prone to suffer major failures. They subsidize short-term lending over stronger, more stable longer-term financing for financial institutions. We get more subsidized short-term debt and less stable, but unsubsidized, longer-term debt. They also make it harder for financial upstarts and regional banks to compete with the big money center banks. Five years ago Lehman Brothers propelled forward the financial crisis, when it filed for bankruptcy. The Lehman bankruptcy proved to be chaotic and the country suffered a major economic setback from which it is still recovering. Yet, if a Lehman-class bankruptcy occurred today, the Bankruptcy Code and the bankruptcy system really couldn't do any better than it did in 2008. So, if a major financial failure gets by the regulators for whatever reason, we still really can't count on bankruptcy to catch the ball. Complex systems, and our financial world is one very complex system, need redundancy in dealing with failure. If one stabilizer fails in a complex system, we want another mechanism to take over to avoid a catastrophic failure. Engineers know that and we should start to make bankruptcy a more viable option than it is today. Second reason for acting on this is that bankruptcy is the first line of defense by statute and regulatory preference. Financial regulators say that they will play the Dodd-Frank title II card only if bankruptcy fails. But, regulators cannot allow a bankruptcy for even a day to see if it works, if we have a major, systemically important financial institution with significant safe harbored securities, because, under today's bankruptcy rules, as soon as the financial institution with major safe harbored financing files for bankruptcy, the exemption for bankruptcy for much of its short-term debt and for its derivatives portfolio will lead its counterparties to rip apart the bankrupts portfolio. There will be no chance to put Humpty Dumpty back together. The third reason to work on bankruptcy as a viable alternative: it is possible that title II may not work. It hasn't been tried. And we should be wary of untested systems. What are the kinds of things we should be thinking about doing for the Bankruptcy Code? First, the kind of collateral that is allowed for short- term lending safe harbors that are exempt from normal bankruptcy should be narrowed. Yes, for United States Treasury securities. No, for mortgage-backed securities. Second, the broad exemption from bankruptcy for safe harbored counterparties should be curtailed. They should be required to stay in bankruptcy for long enough so that the court can sell off bundles of the failed firm's derivatives book intact. The chaotic closeouts in Lehman Brothers are said to have cost Lehman about $50 billion in value. We could do better with a better Bankruptcy Code. Third, the blanket preference safe harbor needs to be better targeted. Preference law has long reduced creditor's incentives to grab collateral and force repayment on the eve of bankruptcy, driving a weak but possibly survivable firm into bankruptcy. Preference law reduces the incentives to grab and demand repayment on the eve of bankruptcy. So, if John owes Jane $1 billion in normal debt and if she holds a gun to John's head and says, ``Repay me,'' when he is on the verge of bankruptcy, she would go to jail for extortion and the $1 billion will be recovered from Jane as a preference in John's bankruptcy for the benefit of all of John's creditors. And the $1 billion preference forced out of John prior to his bankruptcy, will be recoverable even if Jane exerts much less pressure than with a gun. But, if John owes $1 billion to Jane in derivatives debt and she holds a gun to his head to collect, then she will also go to jail for extortion, but she won't have to return the $1 billion as a preference. The derivative safe harbors will fully protect her from the operation of preference law. I would submit that this exempting of blatant grabs from basic preference law is one of the several overly wide aspects of the safe harbors that need correction and narrowing to fit markets better. And there is reason to believe that the collateral grabs that AIG suffered, as it sank in 2008, would have been preferential had the safe harbors not existed. AIG might have failed, would probably have failed and quite plausibly would have been bailed out anyway, but maybe it wouldn't have been done in such dire circumstances and there would have been more regulatory options available, if so much of AIG's obligations were not safe harbored. So, overall, bankruptcy should support financial safety better than it does now. Bankruptcy should be capable of resolving a non-bank, systemically important financial institution with major positions in safe-harbored financing. But, as of today, it cannot. Because it cannot, bailouts are more likely than otherwise and, perhaps even more importantly, system-wide costs to the economy are more likely than they would be otherwise. Bankruptcy should not subsidize the riskiest forms of financing and investment, the shortest-term debts in our financial system. And they shouldn't be facilitating riskier, weaker, systemically important financial institutions. Today, bankruptcy subsidizes this extra risk and short-term finance. Bankruptcy should promote market discipline. Today it tends to undermine that market discipline via the safe harbors, making our financial institutions weaker than they otherwise would be. Several of these problems can be fixed. They are not that hard to fix. And we should fix them. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Roe follows:] [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] __________ Mr. Bachus. Thank you very much. Mr. Smith, do you have any questions or do you want me to? I can go first and then you can. All right thank you. Hearing your testimony, I think we are all thinking back to 2008 in our mind. And we are talking about the failures of what is now called SIFIs and there was obviously almost a ``domino effect.'' I mean, everyday there was a Merrill Lynch or there was a Lehman. For a while there AIG was just--you pick up the paper and what is next? I do think, as we consider what we are going to do, you mentioned redundancy. I think that was your testimony Professor Roe, which I think is tremendously important in a case like that, because I--when you said, you know, title II might work, but it might not work. Or enhanced bankruptcy may work, but it may not. But you have two tracts. And I have told people that 2008 was almost like the economy had a stroke or a heart attack. And it was--you know, as with a stroke or heart attack, you need to get to the patient, time is of the essence. And knowing that, we also add the political theater of what, you know, as these companies either begin to--they become insolvent--there is probably only going to be maybe two or three--it would be unusual to have one, because I think some of the regulations we have now on short-term financing and over leveraging, hopefully we won't have that. But it may be almost a systemic event. And you wonder whether you have to also factor in, is Congress going to try to intervene which even complicates that. I think it is important for us to address this now, not do it in the middle of a crisis where we are being pushed around by changing sentiment. And I think you have all given us a roadmap. One thing that I am struck by, that I did not know at the time, AIG was credit default swaps. I mean this was all pretty risky stuff. It was their insurance business, which was their core business, was totally reserved, there was no--but it was one of their subsidiaries. And I am just wondering, and I--my first question, Mr. Bernstein, in that case you had a subsidiary where the liability was overwhelming the whole company. That single point of entry, does that work in that situation? Mr. Bernstein. I am going to answer this one in the abstract because we had a major involvement in AIG, so I would prefer to keep it to the general. I think if you have significant liabilities in one subsidiary, first of all, if you made some of the changes that permitted you to assume the credit default swaps and other types of instruments rather than having them terminate on bankruptcy, you would have many more options. You could put that subsidiary into bankruptcy and you could preserve those contracts as a book which had value. Or you could recapitalize that entity or do other things. Whereas, you know, currently, with the way bankruptcy works, bankruptcy wasn't an option. Mr. Bachus. Right. And, you know, from your testimony, I think both of you mentioned that the safe harbor includes derivatives. So, it probably included credit default swaps. So, which took, in the case of AIG, almost all their liabilities were outside of bankruptcy or were in the safe harbor. You know, one--there was a lot of discussion back then about good bank, bad bank. Though that is not what you are proposing, is it? Mr. Bernstein. No. It is the single point of entry approach is not really so much good bank, bad bank. It is really taking a group of stakeholders that are subordinated and imposing the losses on them in the private sector, rather than having the public sector support the institution. Mr. Bachus. Yeah. You know, there is. I think Senator Vitter has a bill to basically do away with our largest financial institutions. I know this isn't the subject of this hearing and there is a lot of discussion on that. But, I want to say this, I don't think that is the best alternative because we have to compete on a global marketplace. And I think one of our strengths is we do have some very large companies and financial institutions they are, of course, and I know I am not going to ask you all, at this point, you know, unless you want to discuss that. Does anyone want to volunteer? Mr. Lacker? Mr. Lacker. I will just comment that there is a relevance. There is a connection between bankruptcy reform and strategies like Vitter's or my colleague--former colleague Tom Hoenig, who have advocated dividing up the institutions either by size or activities. You know, what you want to achieve. What those strategies are designed to achieve is a situation in which those firms are resolvable in bankruptcy without government support. I think that is their general objective. And the planning work, that Mr. Bernstein described so eloquently and in detail, that is the way you would deduce, that is the way to figure out exactly what they have to look like now in order for us to feel confident in the future, in extremis, that you could take them through bankruptcy with a fair amount of confidence that it would be orderly enough to be workable. At this point in the process of those ``living wills'' we have just been through, we have just had a second round of submissions, I don't think we know enough now to know exactly what changes we need to make. Whether it is--I am not sure size is the right criteria and I am not sure activities are. I think it is likely to be more--it is more likely to be things like what Mr. Bernstein pointed to, having clear plans, having detailed plans; organizing your legal entities in conformance to your operating activities in a way that makes them severable, if need be, in bankruptcy, if you ever feel the need to spinoff a foreign subsidiary, for example, or handle a foreign subsidiary differently than domestic subsidiaries. So I think all those things are well motivated. But, I think the ``living will'' and the planning process centered around a bankruptcy filing and the fine details of what that looks like, I think that is going to be more informative and more reliably get us to the right kind of solution. Mr. Bachus. You know, AIG, in all of this, is a great example to look at because for--on several different angles. But you did have a foreign subsidiary in London that really was making bets it couldn't afford to lose and in staggering percentages. You also, if you are dealing with a global financial institution headquartered here or even headquartered somewhere else, you--and I am sure somewhere in the Bankruptcy Code, I am not sure how you would--there would have to be some cooperation globally between regulators or between really the court system in different countries. And what would you--how would you address a company that was operating major subsidiaries and business across the globe? Mr. Bernstein. This is also an area where resolution planning is important because, one, you can't assume that local jurisdictions are going to act outside their own self- interests. So, you have to assume self-interest will be the driving force. And you have to design plans that demonstrate that the self-interest of the local jurisdiction is going to be fulfilled by cooperating with the resolution. Many of them do not have a bankruptcy process like we do. They have got a purely administrative process. Some countries go in the other direction and have processes which are purely common law. So, you have to really look at each entity and look at how you demonstrate it is in the local interest to cooperate. Mr. Bachus. All right. You know, again, derivatives would have, if there was a derivative, if they weren't in a safe harbor, if there were some provisions in dealing with those, as opposed to sort of a fire sale, both Lehman and AIG, I think, you know, would be some benefit if that had been in the code. Mr. Roe. Well that--the difficulty with the safe harboring that causes problems for financial institutions with a major derivatives portfolio is that the portfolio is put together as a unit: buy pounds on this side and sell pounds on that side. And the best way to be able to reposition the portfolio is to sell it intact or to sell obvious units of the portfolio intact. The safe harbors make this very difficult because I may have packaged selling pounds with buying pounds together, but my counterparty will tend to closeout this part of the portfolio and my other counterparty might close out that part of the portfolio on terms that aren't particularly favorable to me and make it impossible for me to sell the portfolio somewhere else, if I have a buyer. With some cutback on the safe harbors, we have the potential to be able to put the portfolio together and reposition it and sell it presumably quickly in a bankruptcy. We can't really do that in bankruptcy now. It is possible to do that under title II, but it is not really viable for a firm that has significant derivatives that actually does the filing for bankruptcy. Mr. Bachus. Would, under the Bankruptcy Code that you envision, would all safe harbors be--would there be no safe harbors or would you do it incrementally? Mr. Roe. Incrementally. And there are several things in the Bankruptcy Code that make it difficult or impossible for the good functioning of the derivatives market to work. So, one example, when somebody buys or sells a derivative, they are basically trying to protect themselves against volatility in whatever they are buying or selling. The Bankruptcy Code gives the debtor a nearly unlimited right to reject or assume that contract without any real time limits on that capacity to reject or assume. So, if we had a derivatives contract and I went bankrupt, you would be very worried, legitimately worried that I just might play the market to wait for the moment when the contract has turned favorable to me. So there ought to be some fairly sharp limits on the debtors' capacity to reject or assume a contract. Something along the lines of a few days, a short period in which the portfolio could be assumed and sold intact to somebody else. Mr. Bachus. Okay. And, of course you know, to a certain extent, the Fed assumes some of those to do that, I think. I mean, their book. I mean they assume some of those. I guess they assume some of them were derivatives and that the Fed took on there. Mr. Lacker. Are you talking about the AIG case? I am not familiar with the details of what they assumed---- Mr. Bachus. Yeah. I guess well they mortgaged---- Mr. Lacker [continuing]. How much, I am not sure. Mr. Bernstein. Yes. Mr. Bachus. Mr. Bernstein? Mr. Bernstein. One point to make, which I think was being made by Professor Roe is that--now I think there are really two separate issues here. One, is what it takes to do an effective resolution of a financial institution, in terms of changes to the safe harbors which might be a limited stay and it might be the ability to quickly assume and move the contracts. The separate issue and I think it is, you don't necessarily need to deal with it in financial institution insolvencies, is the more general question of the scope of the safe harbors. And there is a lot of good work being done on that by the National Bankruptcy Conference, the American Bankruptcy Institute Commission and I know Professor Roe is involved in that. But I think it is worth separating those two issues for purposes of this hearing because it is really the former that we really need to focus on for financial firms. Mr. Bachus. All right. I appreciate it. Now, mortgage-backed security, is that a derivative? Excuse my ignorance, but I am just trying to---- Mr. Lacker. No. Mr. Roe. The principal place where mortgage-backed securities would come into the safe harbors would be as a repo. So, if I lent to you with a mortgage-backed security as my collateral, this transaction would be safe harbored under the Bankruptcy Code. One of the problems in the financial crisis is that there was a lot of dumping of the mortgage-backed securities when people realized they weren't worth as much as they hoped they were going to be worth in 2005 and 2006. They turned out to be worth less in 2008. The safe harbors facilitate some of those quick sales in that, if you have done a repo on a mortgage-backed security with me and I go bankrupt, you can take the mortgage-backed security and immediately sell it. In a traditional bankruptcy you can't immediately get to the mortgage-backed security and sell it. The judge has to promise that you will be adequately protected. But, that adequate protection can be realized sometime later on. Mr. Bachus. All right. Mr. Roe. So, that is where---- Mr. Bachus. And I am not---- Mr. Roe [continuing]. The mortgage-backed securities---- Mr. Bachus [continuing]. Thinking that mortgage-backed security wouldn't be a derivative because it is just a basket of mortgages. So, it doesn't derive its value from anything external, I guess, is that correct? Governor Lacker? Mr. Lacker. It is not traditionally thought of--mortgage- backed security is not traditionally thought of as a derivative. Mr. Bachus. Right. Mr. Lacker. There are derivatives that are written to replicate---- Mr. Bachus. Right. Mr. Lacker [continuing]. The returns on mortgage-backed---- Mr. Bachus. And that's what---- Mr. Lacker [continuing]. Securities or to reference those returns. Mr. Bachus. Well, and I, you know---- Mr. Lacker. So, that happens. Mr. Bachus. Some of those were--bets were made to do just that. Mr. Lacker. Yeah. There is a lot of that. Mr. Bachus. Mr. Jason Smith of Missouri. Mr. Smith of Missouri. Thank you, Mister---- Mr. Bachus. A Missouri Tiger fan. Mr. Smith of Missouri. Absolutely. Is there any other? Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Bachus. When there is not a miracle on the Auburn side? Mr. Smith of Missouri. I hope not. It is a miracle for both of us right now. [Laughter.] Mr. Smith of Missouri. My question is to Mr. Lacker. In your view, what are the benefits of resolving the financial firms through the bankruptcy process? Mr. Lacker. So, the alternative are worse, essentially. And the alternatives that we have utilized involve the discretionary deployment of public funds to protect creditors. I think that is an unstable and unsustainable approach. And that is what concerns me about title II as well. The dynamic--the expectation, I talked about that creditors view large financial institutions as ``too big to fail'' and likely to get government support, arose over several decades from the early 70's and it was the accretion of--slow accretion of various precedents that led to the expectation that that is how we are going to behave. We ended up--those precedents resulted from situations in which, faced with a choice between rescuing or not and having the ability to do that, policymakers erred on the side of caution and protected creditors. And this came home, this was most vividly illustrated in the Bear Stearns case. The Bear Stearns had a substantial amount of RP borrowing that was maturing overnight every day, every morning actually. And there were--there was a substantial amount of lending overnight, via purchase agreements, to several other investment banks. And the fear was that, should Bear Stearns not get support and should those lenders get collateral back instead of their cash and have to sell the collateral for an uncertain value, that that would cause lenders to pull away from other financial firms as well. The ambiguity about that was what drove--is what created this awful dilemma for policymakers. And that is an example of the kind of dynamic that set up the precedence that led to the widespread expectation coming into the crisis for this. I think that providing that discretion to policymakers is likely to lead to this dynamic replicating itself in the future. Mr. Smith of Missouri. So, if the Bankruptcy Code was adequately equipped to handle these insolvencies for the financial institutions, what is your belief on this ``too big to fail'' policy? Mr. Lacker. I think that the combination of good improvements to the Bankruptcy Code and the ``living will,'' the resolution planning process, can get us to a position where regulators are comfortable and confident that, should a large financial institution experience financial distress, they are willing to take it through bankruptcy without extraordinary government assistance. And once they are confident about that, we can convince creditors that that is going to be the norm. That will shift incentives in financial markets. That should lead to less short-term funding, less of the fragility that we see, less of the maturity transformation that creates so many problems to begin with. So--and that maturity transformation, that short-term lending like in the Bear case I described, is what gives rise to these terrible dynamics. And that is, I think, our best hope for getting out of the ``too big to fail'' box. Mr. Smith of Missouri. Is the bankruptcy--this question could be for anyone. But, is the Bankruptcy Code prepared for a big company, other than just a financial institution but a big company that may be the largest employer in the United States let us say, that decided to, you know, be insolvent? I mean, is that going to be the same type of situation where it comes back to Congress and we have to bail out this big corporation? Or is the Bankruptcy Code prepared right now to handle a situation that has maybe 200,000 employees? Mr. Roe. I think I could address that. I believe that the bankruptcy system now is capable of handling the bankruptcy of a very large industrial firm. And you could put some of this in, not historical perspective, but perspective over the decades, something I was mentioning while we were offline. When the Bankruptcy Code was passed in 1978, the general thinking was that a large industrial firm, such as the kind of firm you are describing, could not survive Chapter 11. And, in fact, we bailed out Chrysler right after the Bankruptcy Code was passed. And Lee Iacocca, the president and chairman of Chrysler, persisted and was very convincing with the argument that, if Chrysler entered Chapter 11, it would not exit Chapter 11 intact, that consumers would simply not buy cars from a bankrupt Chrysler. Over the subsequent decades, the system has learned how to reorganize very large industrial firms effectively. You know, in the last few weeks I flew American Airlines in bankruptcy and US Air outside of bankruptcy. And I might have been the only one on the plane who just noted that when I got on I was flying a bankrupt airline. It has just become a normal part of business. It will be very good for the economy of the United States if, over the next couple of decades, we could routinize the bankruptcy of financial institutions so that it just happens in the background and works effectively. So, one additional cost of--one additional advantage of bankruptcy over alternatives is, for example, that to use title II, somebody has to be saying this is a systemically important financial institution whose failure would be very detrimental to the American economy. That is the kind of thing that could help propel more panic than we really need to have. If this entity could go right into bankruptcy and be handled by the bankruptcy institutions, which I believe an amended Bankruptcy Code could do, the waters would be calmer and bankruptcy would do better for us. Mr. Bernstein. I would like to comment on that question also. First of all, the Bankruptcy Code was designed for the biggest companies. In fact, it really was designed to follow the pattern of equity receiverships in the 19th century which took the railroads, which were the biggest companies that existed at that time, and reorganized them. But there are two issues that it is very hard for the Bankruptcy Code to deal with. One is, will the company be able to continue in business? And I think what Mark is saying is that, in a lot of instances where people thought companies couldn't continue in business, they have actually been able to sell their product in bankruptcy. Now, whether that would have been true, had the auto manufacturers stayed in bankruptcy for more than 6 weeks, would somebody buy a car with a 5-year warranty and the like? The answer may be that they would, as long as somebody stood behind the warranty other than the debtor. And that gets to the second question, which is somebody has to be willing to finance these entities in order for them to reorganize. And one of the problems in a downturn that goes beyond just the individual company and effects the whole economy is the money may not be available to finance you until you can reorganize. You know, the Tribune Company went into bankruptcy about 4 or 5 years ago. And, at the beginning of that bankruptcy case everyone thought its value was one-third what it turned out to be when it emerged from bankruptcy. And, because of the degradation of value in a depressed market, it may be difficult to find private financing. And there has to be some form of bridge financing, probably other than DIP financing, in that kind of market that is available. And that is why it may be difficult without that sort of liquidity backup for the largest company in America to fail. And that was the experience with the auto companies recently. Mr. Bachus. Thank you. I have got some prepared questions that I would like to go through. There are two for Governor Lacker. These are from staff members or the Chairman. Can you explain why you believe that shifting away from short-term financing for financial firms will increase the probability that they may be orderly resolved through the bankruptcy process? Mr. Lacker. So, Mr. Roe has argued this eloquently in his statement. Mr. Bachus. Right. Mr. Lacker. There is a great deal of maturity transformation that goes on outside the banking system, outside of deposit taking. And it is the type of financial arrangement that is most likely to pin down a policymaker, put him in a box and make him feel as if he needs to rescue creditors rather than let bankruptcy proceed. I think setting the criteria for these large financial institutions that they ought to structure themselves so that they can be resolved in bankruptcy without government-provided ``debtor-in-possession'' financing, with just the debtor-in- possession financing they have planned for is a good criteria. If that means they do less maturity transformation, if that means that they do less borrowing short and holding longer in liquid assets, then I think so be it. I think that the system we have now is--artificially favors the maturity transformation that goes on in qualified financial contracts, particularly in RP lending. And I think reforms to the Bankruptcy Code and the kind of planning, the kind of resolution planning that Mr. Bernstein described, can help us get to a situation where we have a more socially appropriate quantity of maturity transformation going on. Mr. Bachus. You know, look Bear Stearns--in Bear Stearns I have had knowledgeable people that have said to me, ``You should have been able to look at the balance sheet and told they were insolvent.'' So, I think maybe a more clear accounting or examination of their balance sheet. But also they were going through some, what I call, some financial shenanigans of shifting things back and forth. But I am just-- you know there are ways in bankruptcy, there are ways to go back and capture some of that, I think. So that would probably be another advantage of bankruptcy. But anyway, I will get back to it. One of the questions I think sort of tracks on the question I have just asked Governor Lacker, for you Professor Roe. If the safe harbor exemptions create incentives for short-term financing, in your view, how does that make the financial system more difficult to resolve through bankruptcy? Mr. Roe. This will parallel Jeffrey Lacker's comments, in this way, if we have safe harbors for short-term debt but don't have it for long-term debt, we will tend to get more short-term debt that can run off very quickly in a bankruptcy or during a financial failure. So we have rules that facilitate the runoff when we should either want the rules to be neutral or maybe to slow down that sort of runoff. And this actually feeds into the point that Donald Bernstein was making. One of the big problems in a large financial institution bankruptcy would be financing. And this--the remark that I am going to make now is not going to make the problem go away. But, the safe harbors increase the difficulty of financing because some significant portion of the financial structure of a failed financial institution, if they are in safe harbored repo, will runoff immediately and then, in the extreme case, will have to be replaced. If it couldn't runoff immediately the financial pressure would be less on the firm. So, one example, when Bear Stearns filed--when Bear Stearns failed and was taken over by JP Morgan Chase, it had about a quarter of its liabilities in repo. Only a couple decades before its repo level was only about 6 percent of its total liability. When it failed in 19---in 2007, 2008, it is much more difficult for it to go through a bankruptcy because so large a portion of its structure is going to be immediately withdrawn. Mr. Bachus. And I think, just from reading you all's testimony and sort of coming into this, it is just clear that the safe harbors does create some big problems. And the one you have described is pretty clear. I don't know that--Mr. Bernstein, that is to you---- Mr. Bernstein. I definitely agree that---- Mr. Bachus. Yeah. Mr. Bernstein [continuing]. In order to resolve financial institutions you have got to give them the ability to preserve the book of financial contracts and move it on to the continuing entity. Mr. Bachus. And, you know, that seems to be a point if we are going to do something. If we don't do something comprehensive incrementally that would be a good first step that I think would beat a little dissension. This is for Governor Lacker. Do you think there should be any regulatory involvement in the resolution of a financial firm through the bankruptcy process? I guess if we ask 12 different Fed governors, we would get 12 different answers to that question. Mr. Lacker. I don't know. Mr. Bachus. I think that the answer you---- Mr. Lacker. I think it makes--I have seen proposals that give regulators some standing. I think some standing makes sense. But I think you have to be careful about this. I think having a regulator initiate insolvency proceedings seems useful. I think you would want to carefully prescribe through the principles that they ought to be adhering to in making that decision. I think you would want to give them that right, but preserve as much clarity as you can for market participants as to when it is going to be exercised. So, try and do it in a way that provides some bounds around it that provides clarity about when it is going to be exercised. Mr. Bachus. I was just thinking the word boundaries. And, you know, statutorily there ought to be some, with some marginal, I mean, you know, some discretion. But, you would need to define the boundaries of that participation. Whether it was to advise, just to offer advice or to assist, as opposed to not to dictate to them. Mr. Lacker. Yeah. So, the reason I think that is important, is it is important to, in a situation in which there is the potential for creditors to expect government rescues, you want the regulator to be able to force action and force bankruptcy before things unwind, before actions are taken that just make the matters dramatically worse and force the regulator's hand later. So, now, there is other aspects of standing that I don't have a--I really don't have a view on. You know, pleadings and I guess things that these guys are an experts in. Mr. Bachus. Okay. Mr. Bernstein? Mr. Bernstein. Yeah. I generally agree with what has just been said. The--you know, if in fact you retain orderly liquidation authority as a backup, it will be less likely to be used if the regulator has the option of using bankruptcy. So, I think that is probably, on balance, a good thing. The--as to other matters, I mean, there may be other issues such as, you know, if you did this single point of entry approach in bankruptcy that the regulator would want to be heard on. So, there may be other standing issues the regulator wants to be involved in. Mr. Bachus. Well, and I think you could provide for a regulator to actually sit, if not part of the panel, in some position because you would have to assemble people that had the expertise. Mr. Bernstein. Or at least give the regulator the opportunity to be heard on any issue. Mr. Bachus. Okay. And I think the last question is for you, Mr. Bernstein. Based on your experience working with and developing ``living wills,'' setting aside the question of how a financial firm will be financed through a restructuring, what are the major impediments to efficient resolution of a financial firm through the bankruptcy process as the Bankruptcy Code is currently drafted? And actually, you have covered an awful lot of this. Mr. Bernstein. Yeah, I did. Well, I strongly believe that the ability to separate the--first of all, I believe the ability to recapitalize rather than liquidate is extremely important. And I think the tools that are there today will permit it for some entities but not for all entities in the group. And it would be good if the tools were there to have that happen for all entities. I do think liquidity is an important issue and I distinguish that very importantly from capital. The capital losses are going to be suffered in the private sector, but if the liquidity is not there to stabilize the firm through a lender of last resort that is problematic. Banks have the discount window, they can do that; but, broker- dealers don't. So, I think that is an important aspect. And so, I think really focusing on the good work that has been done by the FDIC on single point of entry. And taking that and saying, ``How can we do that in a procedurally appropriate way, under the Bankruptcy Code,'' would be an excellent step. Mr. Bachus. Thank you. Let me--and I am going to conclude with a question that-- and more maybe not a question but to sort of try to encourage some action and that is--you know, National Bankruptcy Conference, the American Bankruptcy Institute, the American Bar Association, the regulators. It would be extremely helpful to the Judiciary Committee and I know the Senate is also looking at this, so this is not something that is--in fact they have had ongoing discussions and we have had discussions with them. So there is a willingness and a desire to make changes in the Bankruptcy Code. But, we--it would be so much easier if, as in the case of some other things, we had a model act or we had a something brought to us. And I know the Senate actually has some draft language, but that would be extremely helpful. It would give us quite a bit of comfort because it would be very hard for us to do that. And so, I would encourage the different--the Conference, the Institute, the regulators to continue discussion and give the Congress some guidance. And, if not, a draft. So, thank you. This concludes the hearing. Thanks to all our witnesses for attending. This is a very--we, in this case, both the democrats and republican agreed that you were as qualified witnesses as any. And without objections all our Members of the Committee will have 5 legislative days to submit additional written questions for the witnesses or additional materials for the record. And this hearing is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 3:50 p.m., the Subcommittee was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X ---------- Material Submitted for the Hearing Record [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] Prepared Statement of the Honorable Steve Cohen, a Representative in Congress from the State of Tennessee, and Ranking Member, Subcommittee on Regulatory Reform, Commercial and Antitrust Law I voted for the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 and remain a supporter of the law. The Dodd-Frank Act's passage by Congress was an acknowledgment of the fact that insufficient regulation led to the problem of so-called ``Too Big to Fail'' financial institutions--that is, financial institutions that were allowed to become so big and so interconnected that their insolvencies threatened to paralyze the Nation's financial system and its broader economy. This situation, in turn, resulted in extreme pressure for a taxpayer bailout when those institutions fell under financial distress. The bankruptcy filing of Lehman Brothers in 2008--the largest bankruptcy in U.S. history, involving more than $600 billion in assets--vividly illustrated aspects of the ``Too Big to Fail'' problem. Lehman's bankruptcy filing greatly exacerbated a financial panic on Wall Street, leading to a severe financial crisis and the greatest economic downturn since the Great Depression, the effects of which we continue to feel today. More importantly, the financial markets' reaction to the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy highlighted the potential limitations of the Bankruptcy Code in handling the resolution of financially distressed systemically important financial institutions. I remain a strong supporter of the Dodd-Frank Act, although I also support certain enhancements to it. For example, I support legislation that would increase the minimum required amount of capital for covered financial institutions under Dodd-Frank. We should also consider the potential need for other enhancements, like adding a representative of the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice to the Financial Stability Oversight Council, created by Dodd-Frank to oversee the stability of the financial system. It is in this spirit that I approach today's hearing, which will focus on whether the current Bankruptcy Code is sufficient to allow for the orderly reorganization or liquidation of systemically important financial institutions under Title I of the Dodd-Frank Act. Whether one supports or opposes the Dodd-Frank Act, we can agree that today's inquiry is an important one. To the extent that modest revisions to the Bankruptcy Code will help ensure that we avoid the need for any future taxpayer bailouts of financially struggling large financial institutions, we should be able to work together on crafting such changes.Prepared Statement of the Honorable Bob Goodlatte, a Representative in Congress from the State of Virginia, and Chairman, Committee on the Judiciary The Bankruptcy Code has existed in this country for well over a hundred years. Over this time, our bankruptcy system has evolved to become one of the most sophisticated regimes in the world. The bedrock principle embedded in the bankruptcy system of providing for the efficient resolution and reorganization of operating firms has allowed our economy to grow and flourish. Nevertheless, a periodic evaluation of the Bankruptcy Code to ensure its adequacy to address the challenges posed by the changing nature of operating firms is one of the fundamental responsibilities of this Committee. I applaud Chairman Bachus for holding today's hearing to examine whether the existing Bankruptcy Code is best equipped to address the insolvency of large and small financial institutions. The bankruptcy process confers a number of benefits to all operating companies, including financial firms. The bankruptcy court provides transparency and due process to all parties involved. Furthermore, bankruptcy case law has been developed over decades, providing consistency and predictability. Additionally, the bankruptcy process has been sufficiently dynamic to administer the resolution and restructuring of complex operating companies with billions of dollars in assets as well as smaller companies and individuals. But despite the bankruptcy system's ability to accommodate complex operating companies, financial firms may possess unique characteristics that are not yet optimally accounted for in the Bankruptcy Code. For example, efficient and orderly resolution of financial firms can require an unusual level of speed. Refinements to the Code might be considered to better provide that speed while still assuring due process. Additionally, in some circumstances the failure of financial firms can pose unique threats to the broader stability of the economy. To account for that, title I of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act requires certain firms to prepare ``living wills'' to plan for resolution in bankruptcy in the event of failure. The Bankruptcy Code is well-crafted to maximize the recoveries of a debtor's creditors while providing an opportunity for the debtor to either reorganize or liquidate in an orderly fashion. It might, however, bear improvements designed specifically for the efficient execution of title I ``living wills.'' These are some of the issues that may need to be examined as part of the broader evaluation of the existing Bankruptcy Code's adequacy to address financial institution insolvencies. I look forward to the testimony from today's excellent panel of witnesses on these important issues. Thank you Mr. Chairman, and I yield back the balance of my time. Prepared Statement of the Honorable John Conyers, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of Michigan, and Ranking Member, Committee on the Judiciary This hearing examines whether current law would adequately address the insolvency of a significant financial institution given what we learned from the near collapse of our Nation's economy just five years ago. As we consider this issue, it is critical that we keep in mind what precipitated the Great Recession. Basically, it was the regulatory equivalent of the Wild West. In the absence of any meaningful regulation in the mortgage industry, lenders developed high risk subprime mortgages and used predatory marketing tactics that targeted the most vulnerable by promising them that they could finally share in the Great American Dream of homeownership. This proliferation of irresponsible lending caused home prices to soar even higher, ultimately resulting in a housing bubble. In the absence of any meaningful regulation in the financial marketplace, these risky mortgages were then bundled and sold as investment grade securities to unsuspecting investors, including pension funds and school districts. Once the housing bubble burst, the ensuing 2008 crash stopped the flow of credit and trapped millions of Americans in mortgages they could no longer afford, causing vast waves of foreclosures across the United States, massive unemployment, and international economic upheaval. And, to this day, we are still dealing with the lingering effects of the Great Recession of 2008 in the form of a sluggish national economy, neighborhoods blighted by vast swaths of abandoned homes, and municipalities struggling with reduced revenues. Fortunately, the Dodd Frank Act reinvigorates a stronger regulatory system that makes the financial marketplace more accountable and institutes long-needed consumer protections. It also establishes a mandatory resolution mechanism to wind down a systemically significant financial institution that cannot be resolved under bankruptcy. The Act also imposes various requirements on financial institutions that will allow regulators to better assess the risks such institutions present to Wall Street and, most importantly, Main Street. A key component of the Dodd Frank Act process requires these companies and the regulators to assess resolution under current bankruptcy law. In recent years, some of the Nation's largest companies have used the Bankruptcy Code to regain their financial footing, including General Motors, American Airlines, and Washington Mutual. Questions have been raised, however, as to whether the Bankruptcy Code can be improved upon to better accommodate large inter-connected financial institutions like those subject to the Dodd Frank Act. Some have even suggested that a new form of bankruptcy relief that specifically deals with these institutions may be the most expedient. There may, in fact, potentially be consensus that some changes to the Bankruptcy Code may be warranted. In any event, today's hearing should elicit some helpful guidance and I look forward to the testimony from these experts. Thank you Mr. Chairman, and I yield back the balance of my time. [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]