[House Hearing, 113 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] A 21ST CENTURY MEDICARE: BIPARTISAN PROPOSALS TO REDESIGN THE PROGRAM'S OUTDATED BENEFIT STRUCTURE ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON HEALTH OF THE COMMITTEE ON ENERGY AND COMMERCE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED THIRTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ JUNE 26, 2013 __________ Serial No. 113-59 Printed for the use of the Committee on Energy and Commerce energycommerce.house.gov U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 85-449 WASHINGTON : 2014 ----------------------------------------------------------------------- For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, http://bookstore.gpo.gov. For more information, contact the GPO Customer Contact Center, U.S. Government Printing Office. Phone 202�09512�091800, or 866�09512�091800 (toll-free). E-mail, [email protected]. COMMITTEE ON ENERGY AND COMMERCE FRED UPTON, Michigan Chairman RALPH M. HALL, Texas HENRY A. WAXMAN, California JOE BARTON, Texas Ranking Member Chairman Emeritus JOHN D. DINGELL, Michigan ED WHITFIELD, Kentucky Chairman Emeritus JOHN SHIMKUS, Illinois EDWARD J. MARKEY, Massachusetts JOSEPH R. PITTS, Pennsylvania FRANK PALLONE, Jr., New Jersey GREG WALDEN, Oregon BOBBY L. RUSH, Illinois LEE TERRY, Nebraska ANNA G. ESHOO, California MIKE ROGERS, Michigan ELIOT L. ENGEL, New York TIM MURPHY, Pennsylvania GENE GREEN, Texas MICHAEL C. BURGESS, Texas DIANA DeGETTE, Colorado MARSHA BLACKBURN, Tennessee LOIS CAPPS, California Vice Chairman MICHAEL F. DOYLE, Pennsylvania PHIL GINGREY, Georgia JANICE D. SCHAKOWSKY, Illinois STEVE SCALISE, Louisiana JIM MATHESON, Utah ROBERT E. LATTA, Ohio G.K. BUTTERFIELD, North Carolina CATHY McMORRIS RODGERS, Washington JOHN BARROW, Georgia GREGG HARPER, Mississippi DORIS O. MATSUI, California LEONARD LANCE, New Jersey DONNA M. CHRISTENSEN, Virgin BILL CASSIDY, Louisiana Islands BRETT GUTHRIE, Kentucky KATHY CASTOR, Florida PETE OLSON, Texas JOHN P. SARBANES, Maryland DAVID B. McKINLEY, West Virginia JERRY McNERNEY, California CORY GARDNER, Colorado BRUCE L. BRALEY, Iowa MIKE POMPEO, Kansas PETER WELCH, Vermont ADAM KINZINGER, Illinois BEN RAY LUJAN, New Mexico H. MORGAN GRIFFITH, Virginia PAUL TONKO, New York GUS M. BILIRAKIS, Florida BILL JOHNSON, Missouri BILLY LONG, Missouri RENEE L. ELLMERS, North Carolina Subcommittee on Health JOSEPH R. PITTS, Pennsylvania Chairman MICHAEL C. BURGESS, Texas FRANK PALLONE, Jr., New Jersey Vice Chairman Ranking Member ED WHITFIELD, Kentucky JOHN D. DINGELL, Michigan JOHN SHIMKUS, Illinois ELIOT L. ENGEL, New York MIKE ROGERS, Michigan LOIS CAPPS, California TIM MURPHY, Pennsylvania JANICE D. SCHAKOWSKY, Illinois MARSHA BLACKBURN, Tennessee JIM MATHESON, Utah PHIL GINGREY, Georgia GENE GREEN, Texas CATHY McMORRIS RODGERS, Washington G.K. BUTTERFIELD, North Carolina LEONARD LANCE, New Jersey JOHN BARROW, Georgia BILL CASSIDY, Louisiana DONNA M. CHRISTENSEN, Virgin BRETT GUTHRIE, Kentucky Islands H. MORGAN GRIFFITH, Virginia KATHY CASTOR, Florida GUS M. BILIRAKIS, Florida JOHN P. SARBANES, Maryland RENEE L. ELLMERS, North Carolina HENRY A. WAXMAN, California (ex JOE BARTON, Texas officio) FRED UPTON, Michigan (ex officio) C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hon. Joseph R. Pitts, a Representative in Congress from the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania, opening statement................ 1 Prepared statement........................................... 2 Hon. Frank Pallone, Jr., a Representative in Congress from the State of New Jersey, opening statement......................... 4 Hon. Henry A. Waxman, a Representative in Congress from the State of California, opening statement............................... 5 Witnesses Katherine Baicker, Professor, Health Economics, Department of Health Policy and Management, Harvard School of Public Health.. 6 Prepared statement........................................... 9 Answers to submitted questions............................... 113 Patricia Neuman, Senior Vice President, The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation.............................................. 15 Prepared statement........................................... 17 Answers to submitted questions............................... 116 Thomas Miller, J.D., Resident Fellow, The American Enterprise Institute...................................................... 34 Prepared statement........................................... 36 Answers to submitted questions............................... 118 Submitted Material Statement of American Federation of State, County and Municipal Employees, submitted by Mr. Pallone............................ 84 Statement of California Health Advocates, Center for Medicare Advocacy, and Medicare Rights Center, submitted by............. 88 Statement of National Association for Home Care & Hospice, submitted by Mr. Pallone....................................... 99 Statement of American Association of Retired Persons, submitted by Mrs. Christensen............................................ 110 A 21ST CENTURY MEDICARE: BIPARTISAN PROPOSALS TO REDESIGN THE PROGRAM'S OUTDATED BENEFIT STRUCTURE ---------- WEDNESDAY, JUNE 26, 2013 House of Representatives, Subcommittee on Health, Committee on Energy and Commerce, Washington, DC. The subcommittee met, pursuant to call, at 9:59 a.m., in room 2322 of the Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Joe Pitts (chairman of the subcommittee) presiding. Present: Representatives Pitts, Burgess, Shimkus, Blackburn, Lance, Cassidy, Guthrie, Bilirakis, Barton, Pallone, Dingell, Engel, Green, Barrow, Christensen, Castor, and Waxman (ex officio). Staff present: Clay Alspach, Chief Counsel, Health; Sean Bonyun, Communications Director; Matt Bravo, Professional Staff Member; Paul Edattel, Professional Staff Member, Health; Julie Goon, Health Policy Advisor; Sydne Harwick, Legislative Clerk; Katie Novaria, Professional Staff Member, Health; Monica Popp, Professional Staff Member, Health; Andrew Powaleny, Deputy Press Secretary; Chris Sarley, Policy Coordinator, Environment and Economy; Heidi Stirrup, Health Policy Coordinator; Alli Corr, Democratic Policy Analyst; Amy Hall, Democratic Senior Professional Staff Member; and Karen Nelson, Democratic Deputy Committee Staff Director for Health. OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. JOSEPH R. PITTS, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE COMMONWEALTH OF PENNSYLVANIA Mr. Pitts. This subcommittee will come to order. The chair recognizes himself for 5 minutes for an opening statement. Nearly 50 million seniors rely on the Medicare program for their health care, and that number may grow to 63 million Americans by 2020 and 81 million by 2030. Medicare's traditional benefit design mirrored the private insurance products, namely Blue Cross Blue Shield plans, available in the mid-1960s. While the private insurance market has undergone significant changes in the last 50 years, Medicare's traditional benefit structure has remained fundamentally the same. Unlike most private insurance today, which has a single deductible for all medical services, traditional Medicare has separate deductibles and copayments for Part A, hospital services, and Part B, physician and outpatient services. The program also charges separate copayments for Part A and Part B services. Today, seniors face great uncertainty about what their out- of-pocket costs will be. Generally, Medicare requires a 20 percent copayment, but without knowing the total cost of a doctor's visit, a hospitalization, or a procedure or test, seniors don't know what that 20 percent means in dollars until after a service is delivered. With no cap on out-of-pocket spending a beneficiary can incur, and confusion about the lack of coordination between Parts A and B, nine out of ten Medicare beneficiaries purchase supplemental insurance. On April 11, 2013, the subcommittee held a hearing titled ``Strengthening Medicare for Seniors: Understanding the Challenges of Traditional Medicare's Benefit Design,'' at which MedPAC Chairman Glenn Hackbarth discussed ways to modernize and improve Medicare's traditional benefit design. As I said at that hearing, everything about our health care system has changed dramatically since 1965. Today's standards of care, and the tests, treatments, and drugs we have access to were not even dreamed of when the program was created. Our expectations have changed as well. Fifty years ago, insurance protected us from catastrophic hospital costs incurred as a result of diseases, which were most likely fatal. With the medical breakthroughs we have experienced in the ensuing decades, many of those diseases have become chronic conditions and we expect our insurance to help us manage them accordingly. Seniors deserve an insurance product that reflects the current health care system, not that of the last century. Today's hearing builds on MedPAC's recommendations, by bringing in policy experts to further explore how we can make the program work better for our seniors. I would like to thank our witnesses for being here today. I look forward to their comments on some of the reforms we discussed at the previous hearing, such as combining Parts A and B under a unified cost-sharing structure, instituting a cap on out-of-pocket spending to protect beneficiaries from the threat of medical bankruptcy, incentivizing high-value care, and others. Thank you, and I yield the remainder of my time to Representative Burgess. [The prepared statement of Mr. Pitts follows:] Prepared statement of Hon. Joseph R. Pitts The Subcommittee will come to order. The Chair will recognize himself for an opening statement. Nearly 50 million seniors rely on the Medicare program for their health care, and that number may grow to 63 million Americans by 2020 and 81 million by 2030. Medicare's traditional benefit design mirrored the private insurance products, namely Blue Cross Blue Shield plans, available in the mid-1960s. While the private insurance market has undergone significant changes in the last fifty years, Medicare's traditional benefit structure has remained fundamentally the same. Unlike most private insurance today, which has a single deductible for all medical services, traditional Medicare has separate deductibles and copayments for Part A, hospital services, and Part B, physician and outpatient services. The program also charges separate copayments for Part A and Part B services. Today, seniors face great uncertainty about what their out- of-pocket costs will be. Generally, Medicare requires a 20% copayment--but without knowing the total cost for a doctor's visit, a hospitalization, or a procedure or test, seniors don't know what that 20% means in dollars until after a service is delivered. With no cap on out-of-pocket spending a beneficiary can incur, and confusion about the lack of coordination between Parts A and B, nine out of ten Medicare beneficiaries purchase supplemental insurance. On April 11, 2013, the Subcommittee held a hearing entitled ``Strengthening Medicare for Seniors: Understanding the Challenges of Traditional Medicare's Benefit Design,'' at which MedPAC Chairman Glenn Hackbarth discussed ways to modernize and improve Medicare's traditional benefit design. As I said at that hearing, everything about our health care system has changed dramatically since 1965. Today's standards of care, and the tests, treatments, and drugs we have access to were not even dreamed of when the program was created. Our expectations have changed, as well. Fifty years ago, insurance protected us from catastrophic hospital costs incurred as a result of diseases which were most likely fatal. With the medical breakthroughs we've experienced in the ensuing decades, many of those diseases have become chronic conditions, and we expect our insurance to help us manage them accordingly. Seniors deserve an insurance product that reflects the current health care system, not that of the last century. Today's hearing builds on MedPAC's recommendations, by bringing in policy experts to further explore how we can make the program work better for our seniors. I'd like to thank our witnesses for being here today. I look forward to their comments on some of the reforms we discussed at the previous hearing, such as combining Parts A and B under a unified cost-sharing structure, instituting a cap on out-of-pocket spending to protect beneficiaries from the threat of medical bankruptcy, incentivizing high-value care, and others. Thank you, and I yield the remainder of my time to Rep. -- --------------------------------. Mr. Burgess. I thank the chairman for yielding. I thank you for having the hearing, and I thank our witnesses for being here today. In its current form, Medicare has made some promises that may be very difficult to keep in just a few short years. It shouldn't be a surprise, since we expect the program designed in 1965 to adapt to the needs and usage patterns of beneficiaries in the 21st century. Enrollment in Medicare could reach well over 60 million people by 2020. In 2013, Medicare costs are estimated to be a little over 3 \1/2\ percent of GDP. That will be almost 6 percent in 2035, so certainly a substantial increase. The primary reason for the increase is the demographic shift--there are more people in the program, baby boomers leave the workforce and join the rolls of retirees. We should undertake an open-minded review of the current benefit design in Medicare and ways to reform it in a way that reflects the needs and expectations of today's seniors. We also must adapt to the needs of future beneficiaries. So let us have that conversation about innovative payment and care programs. Let us empower patients and providers by promoting quality measures that are meaningful to consumers that they can understand. Let us offer incentives in the program to promote better organized, coordinated health care delivery and payment systems. Many of these are tenets guiding our discussions around replacing the Sustainable Growth Rate formula, and that is a good thing, but we must move toward a system that allows all beneficiaries a choice between improved fee-for-service, Medicare Advantage, alternative payment models such as ACOs bundling. Just as each provider should be able to flourish, we must allow patients a choice, a meaningful choice, in how they receive their care. I thank the chairman for the recognition and I will yield back the time. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the ranking member of the subcommittee, Mr. Pallone, 5 minutes for an opening statement. OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. FRANK PALLONE JR, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF NEW JERSEY Mr. Pallone. Thank you, Chairman Pitts, and thank you for holding this hearing today. Improving and strengthening Medicare so that the program can serve as a reliable resource for seniors and the disabled for years to come is critically important. We must continue to examine ways to keep the program solvent as the number of beneficiaries grows from an aging baby boomer population, and we have already made important progress in this area with the delivery-system reforms in the Affordable Care Act. According to the annual Medicare's trustee's report, Medicare spending growth is down and is projected to continue to have slower growth than the overall economy for the next several years, and I am committed to exploring ways to continue moving in this direction and modernizing Medicare so that beneficiaries today and in the future receive the care they need in an efficient and affordable manner. Seniors and individuals with disabilities rely on Medicare to access needed health services. These individuals are some of the country's poorest and sickest. Medicare beneficiaries, half of whom have an annual income under $22,500, spend disproportionately more on health care than the general population. As we consider Medicare benefit redesign, we must protect and improve this population's access to quality, accordable health care. Now, reform should provide greater predictability and security for beneficiaries. For years, my colleagues and I have explored the idea of establishing out-of-pocket limits to protect seniors and individuals with disabilities from catastrophic medical expenses. This is also an opportunity to improve the Medicare benefit design, making it less complicated. The fact that Part A and Part B have such divergent cost sharing and deductibles can seem arbitrary and confusing to beneficiaries. We should examine ways to move away from this model towards one that is more streamlined. Yet we must ensure that any changes that we make to restructure Medicare do not come at the expense of beneficiaries' health or financial security. Any reform, particularly proposals that include changes in beneficiary cost sharing, must take into consideration how the changes will impact a vulnerable beneficiary population. For example, while reducing utilization of unnecessary health services that welcome change, Medicare beneficiaries are not always able to distinguish between unnecessary and necessary care. When faced with higher costs, some beneficiaries will simply reduce their use of services across the board. Older, sicker seniors in particular are more likely to be passive in their care decision-making than the general population and rely on their providers to steer them toward recommended use. That is why we must continue to support comprehensive approaches that help move our health care system to a more value-based system including provider payment models that support value over volume, and the Affordable Care Act laid the groundwork for this, and we must continue down that path. So I look forward to hearing from our witnesses today about their ideas to improve Medicare's benefit structure and look forward to working with my colleagues towards a system that incentivizes high-quality and high-value care while building in protections for low-income and vulnerable populations. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pitts. The chair---- Mr. Pallone. Mr. Chairman, I have three statements for the record that if I could submit--I ask unanimous consent to enter into the record a statement from the American Federation of State, County and Municipal Employees, AFSCME, second, a joint statement from the California Health Advocate Center for Medicare Advocacy and Medicare Rights Center, and lastly, the National Association for Home Care and Hospice. Mr. Pitts. Without objection, so ordered. Mr. Pallone. Thank you. [The information appears at the conclusion of the hearing.] Mr. Pitts. We have more than one subcommittee going at the same time, so members will be in and out today. I apologize for that. At this time the chair recognizes the ranking member of the ranking member of the full committee, Mr. Waxman, 5 minutes for opening statement. OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. HENRY A. WAXMAN, A REPRESENTATIVE IN CONGRESS FROM THE STATE OF CALIFORNIA Mr. Waxman. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate your holding this hearing. The Medicare program been critical to ensuring the health and financial security of seniors and disabled Americans since its inception, and while I know we agree that there are a number of ways we can improve quality and efficiency in Medicare, we should also work on broader health care delivery system reform. I hope we also agree that we must preserve the strengths of the program and its protections for the vulnerable populations that depend on it. It is critical, as we explore this topic, that we are mindful of who the Medicare beneficiaries are. Two recent reports looking at the supplemental poverty measure-one by Kaiser Family Foundation and the other by the Economic Policy Institute-remind us of the financial vulnerability of seniors across the country. Nationally, nearly half of all seniors live with incomes below twice the poverty threshold. In my home State of California, the number is 56 percent, with 20 percent, or one in five seniors, living in poverty. Any proposal to redesign Medicare that doesn't protect these vulnerable seniors or looks to achieve program savings by shifting costs to beneficiaries is not one that I can endorse. I am glad to see that a key element of the models proposed by both Kaiser and MedPAC is that they are cost-neutral to beneficiaries overall. At the same time, I understand that there will inevitably be winners and losers within the Medicare population. I can't emphasize enough the critical importance of ensuring that the full impact, both economically and in health term, is considered across the population of beneficiaries. In our health care system today, among both private and public payers, there is a lack of alignment between cost sharing and value. As Dr. Baicker has indicated in some of her work, cost sharing is a blunt tool that doesn't help beneficiaries distinguish between high-value and low-value services. In the same way that the Affordable Care Act removed cost sharing for age-appropriate preventive services, we know from the private market that reducing cost sharing for prescriptions and follow- up care for people with chronic medical problems improves adherence and health outcomes. There is a lot of interest in eliminating first-dollar coverage as a strategy to reduce unnecessary utilization. Yet we know that in poorer, sicker populations, like those in Medicare, this kind of cost sharing reduces both necessary and unnecessary care. Reducing necessary care and having patients defer appropriate outpatient care and end up in emergency departments or admitted to the hospital is not the outcome we are looking to achieve. More value-based benefit design must be tailored to the beneficiaries. For Medicare, that means building in incentives for high-value care and ensuring protections for low-income and other vulnerable members. In closing, I believe there are a number of ways to improve the benefit design in Medicare that are accountable to both beneficiaries and taxpayers. In the process, we must continue to protect our most vulnerable seniors, and we must make sure that we are not using program redesign as a pretext for achieving program savings by shifting costs onto the beneficiaries. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman. That concludes our opening statements. We have one panel today. On our panel we have today Dr. Katherine Baicker, Professor of Health Economics, Department of Health Policy and Management, Harvard School of Public Health; Dr. Patricia Neuman, Senior Vice President of the Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation; and Mr. Thomas Miller, Resident Fellow, American Enterprise Institute. Thank you all for coming today. Your written testimony will be entered into the record. You will be given 5 minutes each to summarize your testimony, and at this point we will recognize Dr. Baicker for her opening statement. STATEMENTS OF DR. KATHERINE BAICKER, PROFESSOR, HEALTH ECONOMICS, DEPARTMENT OF HEALTH POLICY AND MANAGEMENT, HARVARD SCHOOL OF PUBLIC HEALTH; DR. PATRICIA NEUMAN, SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT, THE HENRY J. KAISER FAMILY FOUNDATION; AND THOMAS MILLER, J.D., RESIDENT FELLOW, THE AMERICAN ENTERPRISE INSTITUTE STATEMENT OF KATHERINE BAICKER Ms. Baicker. Chairman Pitts, Ranking Member Pallone, members of the committee, I am really honored to have the opportunity to talk with you today about this crucial topic of improving Medicare's benefit design, and this offers the opportunity to not only improve the benefit that current enrollees receive but ensures fiscal stability for generations to come. So I wanted to spend a minute talking about balancing two competing factors. I am an economist. I have two hands. I always use that. That is insurance and incentives. The fundamental goal of an insurance product is not only to get people access to needed care but to protect them from financial ruin. Seniors shouldn't have to spend their live savings if they fall ill and their children shouldn't fall into financial ruin to care for an elderly, ailing parent. So it is vital that Medicare offer that kind of financial protection that any good insurance product should. But balanced against that are the incentives that any insurance product creates. When you subsidize care, people consume more of it. We have decades of research that shows that even though it is not intuitive that people consume health care that way, when the price of health care goes down, people consume more and some of that is really valuable care but incrementally it gets less and less valuable to the point that it might even have negative value. So we need to balance those two competing interests in designing a smart insurance product. The question is, how does Medicare do on that balance, and I fear that the answer is right now, not so well. It does not offer vital financial protections. Seniors without supplemental plans face potentially unlimited out-of-pocket costs, as you mentioned, that is not a good insurance product for them. On the other hand, if seniors get supplemental insurance coverage, they then go from having too little insurance to potentially too much where their care is subsidized on a first-dollar way that encourages care of potentially questionable value. We know that in any given year, about 15 percent of seniors if they don't have supplemental coverage face out-of-pocket expenses of more than $2,500 but over 10 years more than half of enrollees in Medicare without supplemental coverage would face more than $2,500 in expenses. The typical Social Security retiree's income is less than $20,000, so that is a huge amount of money for someone with Medicare. That is why 90 percent of them, as you noted, are likely to purchase that supplemental coverage. The challenge is that the extra care that the supplemental coverage creates really falls on the shoulders of the Medicare program. The supplemental coverage only pays for part of it. If an enrollee goes to the hospital one more time than is necessary for good care, that is not good for the enrollee who does not want to be in the hospital but it is also bad for the Medicare program because the program is shouldering most of those costs. So an ideal system would provide beneficiaries with the kind of protection they needed through the Medicare program and then they wouldn't need to purchase the supplemental coverage that raises the cost of the Medicare program and threatens its financial viability for future generations. So how do we improve the benefit design? As Representative Waxman noted, crude cost sharing can do as much harm as good. Nuanced cost sharing, I think, has the potential to improve the quality and value of care that seniors get while reducing unnecessary or low-value care that burdens the current system, and that means that cost sharing for different services should be different. It should be value-based cost sharing where care that is of high value should come with little or no cost sharing at all, and cost sharing should be ratcheted up depending on how the value of care diminishes. Care that has very little health benefit for seniors should come with a substantial copayment. It is important to protect low-income seniors from financial risk exposure. Again, it is an insurance product. You can't expose people to financial ruin, but that cost sharing could be based on income as well. The last point I would like to leave you with is that looking across silos would very much improve the balance between insurance and affordability for the Medicare program, and by that I mean, care consumed in one setting-- pharmaceuticals, doctor's office visits--has implications for care consumed in other settings--hospitalizations, emergency department visits. Patients need to have the right incentives to consume care in the setting that produces the best health value for them. Providers need to think across silos. Physicians should be thinking what are the downstream consequences for emergency department visits, and insurance products need to look across silos. If subsidizing a physician's office visit keeps a patient out of the emergency room, the insurer should be working in a system that encourages that because that is good for the patient and it is good for costs. So improving the program in this way would have far- ranging implications. It would improve the value for beneficiaries, it would improve the fiscal stability of the system. It also has the potential to improve the care consumed by all patients in the Medicare system and privately insured patients. There are spillover effects. If physicians and hospitals do a better job for our Medicare beneficiaries, all patients will benefit from that higher standard of care. Thank you for this opportunity, and I look forward to answering your questions. [The prepared statement of Ms. Baicker follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.001 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.002 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.003 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.004 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.005 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.006 Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentlelady. Dr. Neuman, you are recognized for 5 minutes for an opening statement. STATEMENT OF PATRICIA NEUMAN Ms. Neuman. Thank you, Chairman Pitts and Ranking Member Pallone and distinguished subcommittee members. I appreciate the opportunity to be here with you this morning to talk about restructuring the Medicare benefit design. Medicare provides highly valued health insurance for more than 50 million elderly and disabled Americans, many of whom have significant medical needs and modest incomes. Four in 10 have three chronic conditions, one in four has a mental or cognitive impairment such as Alzheimer's disease, and half live on an income of less than $23,000. Medicare, as we have heard, has a very complex benefit design with multiple deductibles, variable coinsurance per service, and no limit on out-of-pocket spending. To ease concerns about unpredictable and unaffordable medical bills, most have some form of supplemental insurance. Nonetheless, elderly and disabled people in Medicare tend to have relatively high out-of-pocket health care expenses. Health expenses including premiums consume three times the share of Medicare household budgets as it does for non-Medicare household budgets, 15 percent versus 5 percent. Half of all Medicare beneficiaries with incomes below $20,000 spend at least 20 percent of their income on health-related expenses. The idea of simplifying Medicare benefits and strengthening protections for seniors with catastrophic expenses has been one that has been under discussion for years, for decades, and has emerged more recently in the context of deficit reduction discussions. Modifications to the Medicare benefit structure could be designed to achieve any number of goals. Reforms could be designed to generate Medicare savings, to streamline benefits, to add catastrophic protections, to maintain the overall value of the Medicare benefit package while making improvements. They could also be designed to add greatly predictability for beneficiaries, to make Medicare more affordable for people with limited incomes, to reduce the need for supplemental coverage, and to nudge beneficiaries toward high-value services. But achieving all of these important goals at the same time is a very high bar. To understand the potential implications of such proposals for beneficiaries and program spending, the Kaiser Family Foundation with Actuarial Research Corporation examined an approach specified by the Congressional Budget Office in 2011 that included a combined Part A and B deductible at $550, uniform coinsurance at 20 percent, and a new $5,500 cost- sharing limit. This was not a Kaiser Family Foundation proposal; it was the CBO budget option that we analyzed. This option, if fully implemented in 2013, would be expected to reduce out-of-pocket spending for a small share of the Medicare population, generally those who are quite sick, but 71 percent would be expected to face higher costs than they would under the current benefit design in this year. Seniors in relatively good health without an inpatient stay would see their deductible more than triple from $147 under current law to $550 if it were the combined deductible. Yet 5 percent of beneficiaries would be expected to have lower costs than they would. Again, these are sick beneficiaries, people who have inpatient stays, post-acute care, the people who would greatly benefit from a limit on out-of-pocket spending, and over a longer term, a larger share of the Medicare population would benefit from a limit on out-of-pocket spending. MedPAC and the Kaiser Family Foundation recently released an analysis that shows 32 percent of beneficiaries in traditional Medicare would have cost-sharing liabilities that reach or exceed $5,000 over a 10-year period. Benefit redesign proposals can be modified to achieve different objectives, resulting in tradeoffs for beneficiaries for program spending and for other payers. Lowering the cost- sharing limit, for example, from, say, $5,500 to $4,000 would help a larger share of the Medicare population but also reduce the Medicare savings. The reverse would also be true. Raising cost sharing for specific services such as home health care would increase Medicare savings but also shift costs onto seniors and increase the risk that at least some would go without necessary care. Strengthening financial protections for low-income beneficiaries would make the redesign more affordable for seniors with modest incomes but could also erode the Medicare savings unless costs are offset in some fashion. An example of a benefit design that does introduce low-income protections was included in the bipartisan Policy Center initiative that was released earlier this year. Some of the recent benefit design proposals also recommend restrictions or penalties for supplemental coverage, Medigap or employer-sponsored retiree health plans. Adding restrictions to first-dollar Medigap would greatly increase Medicare savings according to CBO, possibly because Medigap enrollees would use fewer services when confronted with higher cost sharing. A premium surcharge would increase savings by raising revenues from seniors who choose to pay the fee in their Medigap or retiree plans but also by reducing utilization among those who respond to the new fee by dropping their coverage, and presumably that would be more likely to be people with more modest incomes. In sum, restructuring Medicare benefit design presents a really important opportunity to addressing longstanding concerns. However, simultaneously achieving the multiple goals of various benefit design proposals is a challenge. Protections for middle- and low-income seniors could be incorporated into a benefit design proposal but may come at a cost and could be compromised if savings are a high priority. I thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Ms. Neuman follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.007 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.008 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.009 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.010 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.011 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.012 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.013 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.014 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.015 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.016 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.017 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.018 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.019 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.020 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.021 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.022 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.023 Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentlelady and now recognizes the gentleman, Mr. Miller, 5 minutes for an opening statement. STATEMENT OF THOMAS MILLER Mr. Miller. Thank you, Chairman Pitts, Ranking Member Pallone and members of the subcommittee for the opportunity to speak this morning on redesign of Medicare's outdated benefit structure. Restructuring the splintered cost-sharing requirements of the traditional Medicare fee-for-service program, separate silos for Part A and B if not D, provides a potential policy reform tool that could achieve the twin goals of saving taxpayer dollars while improving the most essential risk protection benefits for elderly beneficiaries. By increasing Medicare enrollees' cost consciousness regarding more disciplinary initial dollar health care choices, a coordinated set of changes in traditional Medicare's deductible and coinsurance provisions could help reduce current and future levels of Medicare spending. Some of those savings from increased cost sharing at the front end of Medicare coverage then could be used to provide better stop-loss protection against larger catastrophic risks as well as to substantially limit if not eliminate the need and demand for supplemental insurance that imposes excess costs on basic Medicare coverage. However, these fiscal and risk protection benefits must compete with and can complement other policy considerations. They include improved integration of health care delivery, realigned incentives to improve value-based health care, more effective competition between traditional Medicare and private Medicare Advantage plans, and continued protection of the most vulnerable low-income beneficiaries, and this complex balancing act, hard enough in theory, must remain administratively feasible in practice. A number of cost-sharing reform proposals in recent years hit one or more of those target objectives to varying degrees. My written testimony suggests some different ways to set clear policy priorities, accommodate necessary exceptions, and still maneuver through the complexities of implementation and administration. To summarize, traditional Medicare remains a largely unmanaged fee-for-service program that needs to rely on increased but more coherent cost sharing as an important tool though not the only one to help control its excess costs. Hence, overcoming the political cross-pressures that resist any such changes must be worth the trouble by producing significant net budget savings rather than a budget-neutral rearrangement of the chairs on the spending deck. The highest priority should be to protect all seniors against health-related financial risks that they cannot bear on their own. That is not equivalent to hiding from them as many health care costs as possible through third-party payments. Such stop-loss protection, predominant in private insurance plans for decades, is long overdue for traditional Medicare, but in this case, it should be income related rather than set as the same dollar amount for every beneficiary. This major risk approach to Medicare cost sharing should consider the alternative of relying more on a higher rate of coinsurance across a wider range of initial health spending and less on deductibles and lump-sum amounts. This would extend the corridor of cost sensitivity and engage more Medicare beneficiaries in monitoring the real costs of their subsidized care yet temper the full impact of cost sharing in deciding whether to seek any care at all. Amounts of coinsurance-based cost sharing also reset automatically as health care costs rise, and hopefully fall someday. The cleaner and less complicated way to deal with the distortions of supplemental insurance for traditional Medicare enrollees is to improve that program's basic risk protection directly and then set regulatory boundaries on what either individual Medigap plans or employer-sponsored retiree plans can cover. We don't need another new tax on those plans piled on top of the existing debris of dead-weight distortions throughout the tax code. Let us subsidize non-poor seniors less instead of taxing them more. Of course, the poorest seniors must continue to receive special protection against health care cost burdens. Supplemental Medicaid coverage for dual-eligibles would remain in place. More attention should be paid to restructuring current Medicare savings programs for other low-income seniors in a better integrated manger, and in some cases, supplementing them, particularly for those facing high cost conditions. Evidence-based preventive health benefits also should be exempted from expanded cost sharing. Efforts to improve health information and navigational assistance for all beneficiaries but particularly those with cognitive impairments need much more attention and budget support. The particular parameters for restructured cost sharing suggested in my written testimony are merely suggestive starting points but they can help lead us to a reformed Medicare program that relies more on income-related cost- consciousness, enhances true insurance protection against catastrophic risks, and reduces the likelihood of rising premiums, steeper taxes and hidden benefit cuts. Thank you. I look forward to your questions. [The prepared statement of Mr. Miller follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.024 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.025 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.026 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.027 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.028 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.029 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.030 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.031 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.032 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.033 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.034 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.035 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.036 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.037 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.038 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.039 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.040 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.041 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.042 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.043 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.044 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.045 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.046 Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman, and we will now begin questioning. I will recognize myself for 5 minutes for that purpose. The first series of questions are yes or no, and I will ask all of you these questions. So Dr. Baicker, I will start with you. Is it fair to say that you all agree the traditional Medicare fee-for-service benefit design may be outdated and overly complex for beneficiaries? Yes or no. Ms. Baicker. I agree. Mr. Pitts. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. Yes. Mr. Pitts. All right. Second question. Is it also fair to say that the program is need of reform to ensure catastrophic protection for beneficiaries, increased incentives for beneficiaries to seek value-based providers and services and streamline benefits to reflect a modernized benefit structure? Yes or no. Ms. Baicker. Yes. Mr. Pitts. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Yes, depending on how it is done. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. Yes, in general. Mr. Pitts. All right. Is it also fair to say that reforms on such a topic have been discussed for decades by policy experts from both sides of the aisle and political spectrum? Yes or no. Ms. Baicker. Yes. Mr. Pitts. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Miller. We have problems with political markets clearing on them. Yes. Mr. Pitts. All right. Finally, is it also fair to say that given a Medicare solvency crisis, approaches gradually but inevitably pressure to restructure the program's traditional benefit design will only increase? Yes or no. Ms. Baicker. Yes. Mr. Pitts. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. Yes. As the pressures increase, we have to think about how we want to respond to them. Mr. Pitts. All right. Dr. Baicker, given that today approximately 70 percent of Medicare beneficiaries are enrolled in the traditional fee-for-service benefit with the remaining beneficiaries finding greater value in the Medicare Advantage program, wouldn't a modernization of the traditional benefit design ultimately help the majority of current Medicare beneficiaries navigate a very complex cost-sharing structure and effectively avoid the implications of catastrophic illness cost? Ms. Baicker. Yes. I think modernizing the design would allow beneficiaries to consume the care that was right for them in the right setting and from the right provider, and that added flexibility could drive towards higher-value care for all beneficiaries. I think they should have choices about these things. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Miller, do you want to comment? Mr. Miller. Cleaner, clearer signals are important. We may in trying to adjust for everything make the system even more complex. Mr. Pitts. All right. Dr. Baicker, you note in your testimony that cost sharing should be modeled on a value-based framework whereby cost sharing is lowest for services that are most effective at improving health care outcomes. Could you please elaborate? Explain from your experience in looking at private-market options where cost sharing has worked most effectively. Ms. Baicker. Let me give an example from the care of diabetic enrollees who have really high risk of downstream adverse cardiovascular events, and getting them to adhere to their medications, getting them to meet with their physician regularly can improve their health dramatically and reduce downstream costs. There are a lot of innovative ways you can try to get diabetics to be more adherent to best practices, and in the absence of innovation in different types of interventions, we see remarkably low adherence rates to lifesaving treatments that patients just have trouble on their own enforcing, so innovative cost structures where maybe patients even get subsidized to take their medications or where they don't meet with a physician all the time, they sometimes meet with a community care person who coordinates across different patients to provide support for them to take their medications. I think we have seen that the crude tools are insufficient, even for a population where there is effective care available and the downstream consequences are potentially catastrophic for their health, and we see that kind of innovation in the private sector and it is very hard for the current Medicare fee-for-service structure to mimic that kind of innovation. Mr. Pitts. Dr. Neuman, do you want to comment on that question? Ms. Neuman. I would agree with everything. I think the challenge is, who determines what is high value and what is low value, and that is really a major issue in terms of figuring out who would make these determinations. An easy example to think about in terms of value might be generic versus brand for equivalent products, but when you get to the more complex questions involving medical care, these decisions are a little bit trickier to resolve. So I think that is a particularly good example. I know that in the MedPAC recommendation, they talked about delegating this authority, I believe to the Secretary, because they were not prepared to specify when they made their recommendation what exactly is high value and what is not. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. This is a perpetual struggle in trying to get the benefits of what we point to in private-sector private insurance innovation and trying to do that through a comprehensive public program which has a lot of difficulties in making those types of fine-tuned adjustments and being accountable for it. We have got a one-time shot to get the basic shell of a structure for Medicare benefits better, but I think we can't legislate every single particular in that regard. I would suggest that although most of these proposals say well, we will just give the Secretary some discretion, it will all work out, there will be some rulemaking, you need to have some evidentiary boundaries as to exactly how far that is going to go. Most of the examples of value-based insurance design tend to be one-sided. We know how to add benefits that make everybody happy and feel better. We have a lot more problems in taking them away. So you could impose somewhat of a budget neutrality constraint saying for everything you need to put on, if it is going to pay off, something else has to not pay off as well, and that is one way to get it a little more even-handed rather than a one-sided approach. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the ranking member, Mr. Pallone, 5 minutes for questioning. Mr. Pallone. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I wanted to ask Dr. Neuman, many of the proposals for redesigning Medicare's benefit package attempt to balance program simplification through combined deductibles and more predictable out-of-pocket expenses with efforts to improve the program value and efficiency. Many of us would agree that there is a need to simplify the structure of Medicare benefits in ways that make it more understandable and user friendly for beneficiaries and provide them with better protections by providing out-of-pocket spending caps like private insurance plans. Your analysis clearly shows that while a small number of beneficiaries would benefit from their restructured design, a much larger number would see increased out-of-pocket expenses. Can you talk about how with any of these plans there will be inevitably winners and losers? Ms. Neuman. Well, there are 50 million people on Medicare, and everybody has a different set of health care experiences and health care needs and supplemental insurance, which varies across people, and when you change the benefit design, depending on what services people use in a given year, their out-of-pocket costs are going to differ than what they would have been under current law. So in sort of the prototype policy that we looked at, the high out-of-pocket expense of course protects a small share of people. The high out-of-pocket limit protects a very small share of the Medicare population with high spending. That costs. When you add a benefit to Medicare, that increases Medicare spending, and part of the new costs are offset by the higher deductible that so many more people on Medicare will pay because 80 percent of people don't go to the hospital, so 80 percent of people don't incur an inpatient deductible. So for the majority of people who don't go to the hospital, they would pay a higher deductible and so they would see their deductibles increase if this were to be imposed, for example, this year. Mr. Pallone. OK. Now, how can we design a plan that is mindful of the financial insecurity of the large number of Medicare beneficiaries and builds in adequate protections? Ms. Neuman. Well, I think it is tricky if the goal is to produce savings, so in an environment where the overall objective is to produce Medicare savings, it could be quite challenging to build in protections and to lower cost-sharing risk for people with modest incomes. To protect people with modest incomes, one might think about, for example, the Bipartisan Policy Center's initiative which federalizes cost- sharing assistance for people with incomes between 100 and 150 percent of poverty. This is building on the Part D model for low-income subsidies, but adding protections also adds to cost, so to do this, one would need to find a way to offset those costs in some fashion. Mr. Pallone. OK. Dr. Baicker, I know your research has looked at a lot at value-based insurance design, and one of the points you make is that cost sharing as it currently is used in the insurance industry is a blunt tool. It reduces health care spending but in a way that doesn't differentiate between high- and low-value care. It also doesn't take into account the diversity of the beneficiary population who based on their financial and health status are likely to respond differently. So unfortunately, the notion of creating incentives for beneficiaries to make better decisions is often looked at only through the narrow lens of increased cost sharing. Can you talk about ways other than increased cost sharing that benefits can be structured to encourage use of appropriate high-value services and discourage the use of unnecessary services and how important is it to ensure there are not barriers to high-value care? Ms. Baicker. I think you raise a really important point, that cost sharing on the patient side has some potential for harms, especially if it is implemented for all patients in the same way, and on the patient side, the ideal cost sharing might depend not just on the service or the medication or the setting but also on the particular patient. So a cholesterol-lowering drug for a diabetic patient is higher value than that cholesterol-lowering drug for a different patient, and it is very hard to write down a set of rules for specific procedures or specific medications and call them high value and others not when it really varies patient to patient. So it would have to be a much more flexible design on the patient side, which we have seen some experimentation with in the private sector but we are nowhere near achieving the possibilities. On the provider side, I think one could also approach promoting higher-value care by making payments look across silos, and that means not paying more for care in one setting than another setting when the patient might be better off individually in the setting that is less well reimbursed. The reimbursement should really be neutral about where the patient gets the care, so the patient could choose based on what is best for that particular set of circumstances. There could also be payments on the provider side that bundle care across silos and over time. Those bundles have to be big to incorporate, from the physician's office to the hospital to the post-acute care where there is a huge amount of variation in spending in post-acute care, and somebody has to be responsible for that in the provider system so that patients get high-value care after a hospitalization that not only improves their health but keeps them out of the hospital again. So I think we have to approach it both from the patient side but, as you note, from outside the patient side from the provider side as well. Mr. Pallone. All right. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Shimkus, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Shimkus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is great to have you here--an issue that has befuddled the national government, probably since the inception of Medicare in 1965. Those of us that have been around for a long time, I can't think of a time when I haven't talked about the structural deficiency and our promise to pay future generations based upon the formula that we have today. And so thanks for this. I am kind of going to go to--my question is going to be first, if people can shop around for homeowner's insurance and automobile insurance, do you think it is too much to ask for individuals to shop around for health insurance? Why don't we go left to right? Ms. Baicker. I think individuals should have choices among health insurance plans and I think that that would foster innovation in insurance design as well as competition on prices but insurers should be experimenting with the best way to manage diabetic enrollees, for example, and then they should be able to attract more of them by providing higher-value care. Mr. Shimkus. And Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. I think people on Medicare should have choices, and people on Medicare, for example, do have the ability to shop within the Medicare Advantage program today. I think as people get older and have more impairments and cognitive impairments, then the shopping process gets more difficult because it is--I think we have all experienced looking at health insurance and it is a fairly complex enterprise. Mr. Shimkus. It is. I guess the other issue too is if--and I can really understand the debate on seniors at a certain age but it is still seniors at a certain age that are still buying automobile insurance and they are still paying home insurance, and there is a training process too. You can't expect seniors today, a lot of seniors today who are on fee-for-service to automatically move into a competitive-market model and shop around. I think that is really in essence way too much to ask. But you all get the drift I am going. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. We can certainly improve the shopping process for insurance but we sometimes overinvest in it too much. Kate was talking before about getting into broader bundles. What we really want to have is measures of outcomes for all of the players who are providing our care, and that goes beyond just the insurer you select. So we need to think about how seniors can shop more effectively for the team of care they are going to receive or the various folks they go to first further on down the stream, particularly in Medicare fee-for-service where you are not buying as much of an orchestrated, integrated product. So as much as we want to enhance the shopping experience for that front-end idea of what are my benefits, what are my cost sharing, we need to know what actually what is the value of that total experience. Mr. Shimkus. Even in the much maligned or supported ObamaCare or Affordable Care Act, the premise is getting people into markets, State exchanges, where they can shop around, and so this really is a segue to that whole issue. If you can then move the public at large either by their employer or the individual citizen, in essence forcing them to shop around in an individual exchange, why isn't the segue then into future generations move these people then into a market-based system of health insurance providers for Medicare and Medicaid? And that might even also address the payment disparities that you see from these two programs, which the majority would much rather pay the Medicare rate than they are going to receive on a Medicaid reimbursement, which really distorts this whole funding scheme. Does anyone disagree with that, or anything to add? Ms. Baicker. I think making it easy for people is key. Competition doesn't work if people aren't able to evaluate the options in front of them and aren't able to move, and that is about making information transparent, and it is also about sort of smoothing pathways. We know that it is hard for people when they have so many different choices and the information is varied to make wise decisions. Mr. Shimkus. Let me just jump in because my time is short, but Dr. Neuman, you kind of mentioned it, and you were kind of leading up, I was kind of building momentum here for this thing, does Medicare Advantage strike this balance to some extent of allowing people choices and systems and a way to shop around that could be in essence kind of rolled up writ large, I think? Ms. Neuman. You know, it could. People have the choice of traditional Medicare and Medicaid Advantage plans, and then if they choose Medicare Advantage plans, they can choose among them. We don't really know very much actually about how people are choosing plans and whether they are choosing the best plans for them. We know in the Part D marketplace that people are actually not making choices in terms of which plan would reduce their cost the most. So we still are pretty early on in this experiment in terms of understanding how seniors behave in the marketplace. Mr. Shimkus. But Part D, I don't know the recent approval ratings or the like but it is still well received. Ms. Neuman. Oh, yes. Mr. Shimkus. And approval ratings are higher than any health care thing we passed ever in this chamber. So it is a very successful model. I yield back my time. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the distinguished ranking member of the full committee, Mr. Dingell, for 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Dingell. Mr. Chairman, I thank you for your courtesy, and I thank you for holding this hearing today. It is very important. As most people know, my dad was the originator of Medicare, and I was proud to cosponsor the legislation and to provide over the House of Representatives during its passage. The program has endured as one of the most significant pieces of legislation in our Nation's history and is it of enormous importance to our senior citizens and to a lot of other people. I recognize that it is time for review on a continuing basis of this great program, and I believe that we can do so without limiting or decreasing benefits that are available to our seniors today as we look to see to it that it is conducted in the most efficient way from the standpoint of costs and other things. Now, the testimony focuses today on a number of proposals on how to reform Medicare. I want to focus my questions on the impact these programs and reforms would have on seniors. Dr. Neuman, these questions are directed to you as spokesman for the Kaiser Health Foundation, and I want to thank you and the other members of the panel for being here. Your assistance is much appreciated. Doctor, is it correct that nearly one in four of Medicare beneficiaries are only in fair or poor health? Ms. Neuman. Yes, sir. Mr. Dingell. Doctor, is it also correct that 40 percent of Medicare beneficiaries live with three or more chronic conditions? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Dingell. Doctor, do more than half of Medicare beneficiaries live on incomes of less than $22,500 a year? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Dingell. Dr. Neuman, does Medicare have a limit on out- of-pocket expenses for beneficiaries? Ms. Neuman. No. Mr. Dingell. Dr. Neuman, is it correct that Medicare beneficiaries with incomes below $20,000 per year spent something like 20 percent of their income on health-related expenses? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Dingell. Now, Doctor, thank you. It is clear that we have many beneficiaries for Medicare who have serious health needs and very limited resources to pay for their care. Placing cost-sharing requirements on this population is going to have to be done very carefully or it will have an appalling negative impact on their health and financial security. Now, the Kaiser Family Foundation recently commissioned a study, which has been discussed this morning, on the impact of three reforms that have been proposed by many different groups: a unified copayment for Parts A and B, a 20 percent coinsurance for Medicare services, and a $5,000 annual limit on out-of- pocket spending. Dr. Neuman, did this study find that 71 percent of the beneficiaries would see an increase in out-of- pocket costs to them if this plan was implemented this year? Ms. Neuman. Yes. Mr. Dingell. Now, Doctor, did this study also find that aggregate spending among Medicare beneficiaries would increase over $2 billion? Ms. Neuman. Yes, sir. Mr. Dingell. And Doctor, I hope you understand, I am doing this so we can get an awful lot into the record as opposed to putting you in any kind of a difficult place. Doctor, do you believe that these proposed reforms would also lead to increased costs for beneficiaries if not structured properly? Ms. Neuman. Yes, I think there is a risk that that could happen. Mr. Dingell. And I believe you are suggesting that if we do this, it should be done with all the facts and with a great deal of care. Ms. Neuman. That is correct. Mr. Dingell. Now, I think we need to take a good, hard look at the ways that Medicare can be reformed so that the program continues to provide security for our future generations. However, we must ensure that such reforms are not simply shifting costs from the federal government to senior citizens who are incapable of properly meeting those demands. Medicare is a promise to our senior citizens, and we need to keep our word to them. I am confident that we can improve the program while protecting access to care if we work carefully together in a bipartisan manner. Mr. Chairman, I want to thank you for recognizing me. I want to commend and thank our panel, especially you, Dr. Neuman, and I hope that as we proceed forward, we will do so with exquisite care. We have a program of vital importance to our senior citizens, one which must be protected and one which with unwise tinkering can cause no end of problems. I also note that if properly done, it is a program which could continue to persist in its service of our people for a long time into the future and that the corrections are not disastrous if properly done. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back 1 second. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentleman from Louisiana, Dr. Cassidy, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Cassidy. Hello. Thank you all. I enjoyed your testimony and your written testimony. Mr. Miller, I think I may end up quoting some of yours but I won't quote it here. Mr. Miller. It is there for your use. Mr. Cassidy. Dr. Baicker, I think it may have been your testimony where you hint at, indeed, it may not only be expensive to have overutilization of services but also harmful to the patient's health. I see both of you nodding your head. I agree with that totally. So let us be clear: When we speak about using services more widely, it is not only monetary but most importantly it is about making sure that patients' health is not harmed. Yes? Ms. Baicker. I agree that not harming health is clearly first and foremost, and then there is also care that is of potentially zero benefit or very small benefit that is really expensive. Mr. Cassidy. OK. Now, one thing that you read about is the activated patient, the activated patient whose expenses are 8 to 21 percent lower than the person--and I gather there may be even some empiric evidence that the activated patient is a healthier patient. Just for those listening who may not know, an activated patient fully participates in their care both physically and financially. Now, have any of you all--and try to keep your answers brief, please--do any of you have specific suggestions or the things that you suggested do you feel as if they would create the so-called activated patient, the one participating both in their health decisions as well as their financial decisions. For example, Mr. Miller, you speak of value-based purchasing as do maybe all three of you. I don't really think of that as creating an activated patient. That is actually just saying we are going to pay for this and not pay for that. Mr. Miller. The decisions are made before the patient is asked about it, and we are steering them in that particular direction. Now, we can do that in some areas. Certainly the best evidence tends to be in the prescription drug area. That is largely accommodated through Part D already in Medicare. So I think we can move that mostly off the table. Mr. Cassidy. So by incentivizing patients to go to generics and allowing them to save money, you create an activated patient who is both looking at the cost but also doing so improving---- Mr. Miller. Looking at the cost opens the door to thinking about the value. Cost is only the opening consideration, but if you haven't gotten someone's attention with the cost, they may not think about how that balances out against the qualitative tradeoffs. Mr. Cassidy. Now, Mr. Miller, I like your kind of testimony, if you went to a higher coinsurance but you still had the same limit on out-of-pocket, you may achieve both, maybe more upfront costs but---- Mr. Miller. You are trying to expose more patients across a wider range of decisions to thinking about the care they receive. Mr. Cassidy. Now, let me ask you this, and this is something I haven't completely worked through, so if I totally fumble, please forgive me. As some hospitals are purchasing physicians' practices, typically procedurally based, and they are beginning to bill under Medicare Part A as opposed to Part B, effectively we are having what you are describing in which the deductible for that Part A service is often greater than it would be for the equivalent Part B. We are seeing a downward trend in Medicare spending. I tried to learn if that is attributable to this phenomenon. That is more difficult than its seems like it should be. I have not yet been able to determine that. But it seems to me that we may be seeing examples of what you are describing, bringing it into Part A, increasing the upfront deductible and coinsurance costs, and yet there has been no decrease in health quality and there has been a decrease in spending. Any thoughts on that? Mr. Miller. Well, I have not looked at that data. I mean, we have got a different type of thing going on where hospital outpatients, because it is reimbursed more generously than other outpatient---- Mr. Cassidy. But that costs the patient more. Mr. Miller. Which is the problem of all these type of siloed payments. Other private parties will find ways to maneuver around them. Mr. Cassidy. Oh, I accept that as a different thing, but just my general point, that we have effectively increased the amount that is out of pocket for patients and we have actually seen a decrease in spending in the Medicare program, in the Part B program. Mr. Miller. Right. Mr. Cassidy. Any thoughts on that, Dr. Baicker or Dr. Neuman? Ms. Baicker. I think you hit on a key point that innovative insurance companies can drive patients to be more engaged in their own care, and that innovation could come in the form of cost sharing or it could come in other ways that insurers think of to get the patients engaged and having them have that flexibility would open a wider set of---- Mr. Cassidy. What are some other examples of how they could be engaged besides cost sharing? Because clearly we need patient engagement. Ms. Baicker. I think there are examples of getting patients to interact with a wider set of patients who have conditions like them, of getting text messages to remind them of things, of getting---- Mr. Cassidy. I have heard about that. Has that actually been shown in some sort of peer-reviewed double-blind way to actually work? Ms. Baicker. I think text messages do increase adherence to medications, that part of not taking your meds is not about the copay, because you already have the drugs, but taking them regularly, it is a skill, it is a habit, and there has to be skill building that if you don't have the right incentives, insurers don't engage and providers don't engage in patient---- Mr. Cassidy. So if you, though, that is not the insurance product per se but rather the administration or patient care aspect of it, correct? Ms. Baicker. But if the insurers and the providers have the right incentives, then they can innovate in that dimension that benefits patients by getting them more engaged, and you need a system that incentivizes upstream for that to happen downstream. Mr. Cassidy. Thank you all. I yield back. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentlelady from Florida, Ms. Castor, 5 minutes for questions. Ms. Castor. Well, thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you all for your expert advice provided to the committee. I want to start off by saying thank goodness for Medicare when you look back over the past decades what security that has brought to our families all across America, our parents and grandparents. We don't have to worry about our older neighbors falling into poverty because of their health issues as they get older. And now with the Affordable Care Act, Medicare is even stronger. We have already adopted very important reforms moving benefit. The benefits for Medicare beneficiaries are better. The life of the trust fund has been extended. It is not great, though, and I worry because I see this huge population of the baby boomers now coming into Medicare as they turn 65, and I think this is the right time to look at reforms. One recent proposal was called the Medicare Essential proposal by Karen Davis and others in the Commonwealth Fund. They propose to combine Parts A, B, and D with a single deductible, copayments, and a ceiling on out-of-pocket costs. In addition, it would build incentives for beneficiaries to choose the high-value care we have talked about this morning including having them join those primary care practices that quality as patient-centered medical homes and using providers participating in alternative payments like ACOs. I have seen some of these in Florida where they are very intensive. The nurses are on the line constantly with their patients talking about smoking cessation, taking their medications, but it is still very difficult. And the inherent part of that proposal is the assurance of equitable access for low-income beneficiaries. Dr. Neuman, what is your view of that proposal? Do you have any criticisms or do you want to highlight the good parts of it? Ms. Neuman. Well, I think it is a proposal--you are looking at a lot of proposals that are trying to achieve similar goals. This proposal is certainly worth looking at, and particularly the features that would provide the catastrophic protection and to encourage people on Medicare to move toward systems where there are incentives to improve the delivery of care, and I think there is a lot of interest in giving beneficiaries access to the kinds of care coordinators, nurse practitioners, the kind of services that you were talking about that you have seen, and that would be encouraged under this proposal. It has a relatively low limit on out-of-pocket spending. It has a fairly low deductible. So I think it recognizes the needs of people with modest incomes, so I would encourage you to take a look at that. Ms. Castor. OK. Doctor, do you want to comment on that? Ms. Neuman. Yes, I do think that there are a lot of common threads in these proposals where there is a consensus emerging that the protections that Medicare affords are vital and have to be preserved but that moving patients towards programs that foster whole health, that look across silos are really engaged with patients to activate them and to ensure that they are consuming the care is actually going to produce help for them with the highest value. There are a lot of common threads. Optimistic? I don't know if that is reasonable that we do it that way. Ms. Castor. Mr. Miller? Mr. Miller. Well, I looked at the Part E proposal, which is somewhat of an update of an older one a couple of months ago. I appreciate the creative use of the Medicare alphabet but I think it is really aiming for Medicare Part U, universal, which trying to squeeze out private competition, if you look at the actual underpinnings of it, and there are a number of---- Ms. Castor. Well, that raises another point, because I think the Medigap policies, the supplementals, I get your point about are they encouraging overutilization, and they seem to be ripe for reform and cost savings too. When you look at traditional Medicare, the administrative costs are only 2 percent. You look at those Medigap policies, and administrative costs are 20 percent. That is awfully high. Dr. Neuman, where should we be headed in reform of those supplemental policies? Ms. Neuman. Well, the loss ratio requirements haven't been looked at for some time, so that might be something you might want to look at with Medigap policies. I think the issue with Medigap is, it may drive up utilization and spending and Medicare services but people really rely on Medigap for the security that it provides. People seem to want protection. They don't seem to want to have an unpredictable, unaffordable medical expense occur throughout the year. There are kind of two sets of proposals out there on supplemental insurance. One would prohibit first-dollar coverage for Medigap. The other is a surcharge approach or a tax approach which would tax both Medigap and employer-sponsored plans, and they would have very different effects, depending on how they are implemented. Ms. Castor. Thank you very much. I have run out of time. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentlelady and now recognizes the gentleman from Kentucky, Mr. Guthrie, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Guthrie. A perfect trend. My friend from Florida led right into my questions. I was going to talk about Medigap. A lot of times we talk about transparency in pricing and you can't find the pricing in health care, and if you go to the Houchins IGA grocery store in Bowling Green, Kentucky, there is a price on everything, because if they didn't have a price on anything, nobody would buy anything because it is out of their pocket. They have got a sign tall enough you can see what their gallon of gas costs going down I-65 at 70 miles an hour. So that is just a problem. But I will tell you this: if I paid $100 a month to Houchins IGA and they allowed me to come in and buy anything that I wanted to because I paid $100 a month, not only would prices go away, I probably wouldn't make too intelligent of at least value based. I would buy the T-bone steak every time I went in. And so there was a 2009 MedPAC study--I think we just started getting into it--about beneficiaries with first-dollar coverage and they use the system about a third, or they have a third higher medical costs than those with no supplemental, and the first-dollar coverage regardless of type of plan results in higher Medicare spending. And in the June study, MedPAC made some recommendations to address this. I think we talked about one is a copay, a fixed-dollar copay, and the excise tax that you talked about. I have some concerns with it. One is that if, say I pay $100 a month for it and all of a sudden they say you are going to have to pay a tax so you have to pay $110, well, that $10 will go into the trust fund, I get it, to help offset my cost. That doesn't change my behavior at all. So that just doesn't seem to--other than putting money in the system, it doesn't seem to have any change in me using a third more. Ms. Neuman. I think it might have an effect. The effect might be different for people with lower incomes. So for people who can afford the extra $10 in your example, they pay the $10 and they keep their coverage and life goes on and they use services as they did. For people who can't afford the $10, they would probably give up their supplemental coverage or they may give up their supplemental coverage and then they would face the true costs of whatever services they used and---- Mr. Guthrie. But that would have a negative impact on the poor and the excise tax would have a negative impact on the poor recipient. So it could price people out of the market is what you are saying? Ms. Neuman. That is right. Mr. Guthrie. But I guess I would like to talk just--I have got 2 \1/2\ minutes--of this whole first-dollar coverage and what you think should change that. I think Mr. Miller is about to start. Mr. Miller. I was just going to add, in the Medigap area we already have plenty of evidence that people buy plans that cost more than $1 for a $1 in benefits. So we can go through the, you know, approach of taxing them a little bit more and making it even less of a good deal. I suspect we will still have some people buying it. But the 2009 study was very well crafted, because there has been a lot of older evidence on the extra costs that are thrown off by supplemental coverage. I think it dealt with some of the criticism of the earlier work and made it quite clear that more so for individual Medigap-purchased insurance, less so for employer-sponsored insurance, but all of them have a higher cost impact on Medicare, and that is not covered by the Medigap premium or the employer costs; it is passed onto every other Medicare beneficiary. Mr. Guthrie. But it continues to add into that ``I don't have to price my health care because it is being covered from first-dollar coverage.'' Dr. Baicker? Ms. Baicker. And in general, when you tax things, people consume less of them, and the goal I think would be to reform the basic Medicare benefit so that people have the vital financial protections and didn't need the Medigap policies as much, and then pricing the Medigap policies would take into account the extra cost they impose on Medicare and other Medicare beneficiaries and would hopefully induce people to move towards plans that didn't have so much first-dollar coverage because they were getting their out-of-pocket protections from the main Medicare program. They would then scale back the consumption of care that is of less value and everybody's care would be a little more affordable. There are a lot of steps in that chain, and there is a lot of uncertainty about how big each of those steps would be but we know that Medigap policies today are priced much lower than their true cost and so we are subsidizing the kind of care that produces very little health, and that doesn't seem like a great way to continue. Mr. Guthrie. Any further discussion? Dr. Neuman, any other points? Ms. Neuman. Well, we are subsidizing--some of what we are subsidizing probably produces good health but some of it may not, so there is a mix there. Mr. Guthrie. But there is a desire in this. We have to recognize that people want to insure themselves against ``I just don't want to have to face this. I would rather pay a little bit each month and not have to face it.'' Ms. Neuman. Many people on Medicare are living on fixed incomes so they don't like the idea. Mr. Guthrie. Exactly. So it is a good benefit. Ms. Neuman. And I think the issue here is in a benefit redesign, if the deductible is relatively high and the out-of- pocket limit is relatively high because of budget constraints, then it may not dampen the demand for supplemental coverage if people still will feel exposed to a high deductible and they can't afford to get to that limit. Mr. Guthrie. I think I just ran out of time. I appreciate it. I yield back. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentlelady from Virgin Islands, Dr. Christensen, for 5 minutes for questions. Mrs. Christensen. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Welcome to the panel this morning. Dr. Neuman, I really appreciate your testimony, especially your focus on economic circumstances and health status of Medicare beneficiaries and they need to be mindful of both the intended and unintended consequences of benefit design. Broad cost-sharing requirements have a significant impact, as we have said, on low-income seniors. I worry that even with an attempt to build in low-income subsidies, this could still create barriers to necessary health care for vulnerable seniors and worsen health disparities that already exist. Could you comment on that further? Ms. Neuman. You raise a good point. There are enormous disparities in income and assets of seniors by race and ethnicity. So people of color would be negatively affected by an increase in cost sharing unless there were adequate protections. That is a real issue. Mrs. Christensen. And we have heard a lot this morning of course because the focus is on Medicare today, but Medicaid is also an important program for millions of seniors and benefit design could affect that. Could you talk about the role Medicaid plays for these low-income individuals and why it is so important? Ms. Neuman. Yes, Medicaid plays an enormous role in providing financial security for people with very low incomes and very modest assets. So today Medicaid fills in the gaps, helps with cost sharing, helps with premiums, provides other benefits, but not all low-income qualify and are covered by Medicaid. So for those who are just above the Medicaid eligibility level, they are responsible for their full cost- sharing obligations and premiums and uncovered services are everyone else is and may or may not be able to afford supplemental coverage. Mrs. Christensen. Right. I will just take off from that. Some people have proposed limiting the amount the federal government pays for beneficiaries, either through a cap or per- person payments or cap on total federal spending. How might such a proposal affect coverage for access to care for these vulnerable populations? Ms. Neuman. I think it would shift the risk from the federal government or State governments to the Medicare population and the poorest on Medicare. Mrs. Christensen. I am just curious. As a physician who took care of Medicare patients, a lot of comments have been made about the increased cost when there is not significant cost sharing. In my experience, Medicare did not pay for unnecessary care, so is it a guarantee that just having no cost sharing increases the cost? Because it might increase visits but if Medicare doesn't pay for visits that are unnecessary, tests that are unnecessary--and anyone can respond. I am just curious, because I have had things denied reimbursement. Ms. Baicker. So I think you are highlighting that the black-and-white nature, necessary versus unnecessary, is much messier in the real world. There is a continuum of value that care produces from urgent lifesaving care to care that I do think is unnecessary or even potentially harmful. If you look at the example of testing for prostate cancer in older men, Medicare pays for that, and there is an age beyond which the test actually can do more harm than good because it is detecting cancers that would not actually kill the person and it subjects the patient to downstream procedures and costs that may actually do them harm, and Medicare does pay for that. At the same time, it makes mistakes in not paying for stuff that is valuable. So I think there are both types of mistakes in the current program: paying for stuff it shouldn't and not paying for stuff it should. Mrs. Christensen. Well, I also think on that prostate issue that we probably need some more research done and information, but providers can make judgments even at an older age with a person that has a positive or a high PSA. I am going to yield back the balance of my time, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentlelady and now recognizes the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Bilirakis, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Bilirakis. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate it very much, and I thank you for your testimony. The question is for Mr. Miller. First question, in your testimony you talk about various ideas of structuring benefits with different cost shares and deductibles. Is it worthwhile to have multiple Medicare plans in the marketplace? First question. We could establish an actuarial value and allow various plans of different premiums, deductibles and cost shares. This would allow seniors to choose a plan that fits their lifestyle and health status rather than a one-size-fits- all plan Mr. Miller. It is correct that there is more than one way to configure insurance benefits, and certainly seniors should look forward to that. I think what you are hinting at is a better structured version of the current competition we have between fee-for-service Medicare and Medicare Advantage plans and the premium support model, which could provide that type of more vibrant competition. You have to have a starting point, though. How is the basic benefit defined legally from which then plans can vary in terms of how they meet an actuarial equivalent of that or charge a supplemental premium for people who want more coverage than what that basic one is how the bids are determined. There is a harder question as to whether or not we can allow the Medicare fee-for-service program to offer more than one version. People are a little resistant to that, but if that enhanced Medicare fee-for-service with other benefits is not subsidized, where it is actually charging an extra premium that people have to pay the cost of it, then that would be the type of level playing field competition that we always talk about in theory but never deliver in practice. Mr. Bilirakis. Thank you. Next question for all. I know we have touched on a lot of these issues, but I want to give you an opportunity to elaborate a little bit. This one has to do with transparency. One of the great challenges of health care is the issue of price transparency. Health care is perhaps one of the biggest sectors of our economy where no one really knows the cost of service. I go to the doctor, I pay a copay, I know what the cost of that visit is before I go. I go to the doctor, I pay a coinsurance, I don't know what the visit will cost me until after the visit. When designing a new benefit structure, how can we increase the level of transparency in the system so beneficiaries can know what their costs will be before they even visit the doctor? And that is a question for the entire panel. Ms. Baicker. So this is something beneficiaries complain about rightfully a lot, that they have no idea how much a service costs, and physicians aren't really in the business of giving them that information either, and so one model is to go to copayments where you know $10, $20. It is known ahead of time. Another model is to make sure that the prices are easily knowable to the patients beforehand so they can make informed decisions and so their providers can help them too. If the providers don't know how much something costs, how can they make recommendations that are in their patient's best interests? Mr. Bilirakis. How do you suggest we do that? Ms. Baicker. Well, there could be a requirement that prices are transparent, and that is going to depend on what insurance product the patient has and what has been negotiated between the insurer and the provider. There could be a move towards copayments instead of coinsurance. Either could achieve similar ends in terms of transparency but would have different effects, I think, on the negotiations between insurers and providers, not in the case of fee-for-service Medicare, of course. Mr. Bilirakis. OK. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Well, I would just say it is less of an issue with fee-for-service Medicare than it is in the commercial market for the rest of us who are out there wondering what the price of various services are. I think copayments would be a lot easier for people in Medicare to understand. That is what a lot of the Medicare Advantage plans are doing now. And I think it would just be easier to anticipate well, if I go to the emergency room versus go to my doctor, I am going to pay this much more so I better--I should try to wait and see my doctor. Mr. Miller. If you want beneficiaries to know the real costs of the care, copayments are somewhat, you know, sometimes well, sometimes arbitrarily assigned and they tend to converge in certain clusters. If you go to a coinsurance approach, if you know the coinsurance rate and it tends to be uniform, you automatically know what the full cost of the covered service was. It just a simple matter of multiplication. So you both see what you are paying and you know what the all-in cost was that other people are picking up. Mr. Bilirakis. Very good. Mr. Miller, traditional Medicare fee-for-service operates in two different silos, Part A, of course, and Part B, without either part talking to each other. Medicare Advantage provides a comprehensive benefit with better coordination between a hospital and the outpatient settings. Do we have data evaluating Medicare Advantage against traditional fee-for-service? Does Medicare Advantage provide lower costs and better outcomes compared to the traditional fee-for- service? Mr. Miller. We have some studies which if you look at certain areas will say they are more effective in what they do. I don't think there is a comprehensive evaluation which can do an apples-to-apples across-the-board evaluation of that because the programs operate so differently. In addition, although we have changed some of the rules for the way the bids are set up and how they are reimbursed, we have not had them operating on the same level playing field entirely. So for a period of time we paid more to the Medicare Advantage plans in order to bring in more service and more enrollees. Now that is being pulled back. We are not exactly at a total equivalence to make an all- in comparison. Mr. Bilirakis. What lessons have we learned from Medicare Advantage, the entire panel, if we redesign traditional Medicare? Ms. Baicker. So I think Medicare Advantage has evidence of better coordinated care, although not uniformly lower costs. I do think there is the potential that when Medicare Advantage promotes best practices and higher-value care, that can have system-level consequences because the same hospitals and the same providers treat MA patients in traditional Medicare patients so if they improve their efficiency for a critical mass of patients, that can have system-level ramifications, and we see some evidence of those spillovers. Mr. Bilirakis. Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. In a recent review of the literature, we have found that there is sort of mixed evidence, and the evidence is pretty early, so there is some evidence of some positive outcomes and indicators from Medicare Advantage plans but not all Medicare Advantage plans are alike, and so I think it will be important to see what constitutes an effective plan and what produces positive outcomes, and I think we don't quite know yet. Mr. Bilirakis. Mr. Miller, what lessons have we learned? Mr. Miller. We have learned that it is pretty hard to do this, particularly through political means, and I think the lesson we should take is perhaps if we can get it out of Washington into the hands of doctors and patients, we might actually begin to sort this out and find a better balance. Mr. Bilirakis. Very good. Mr. Pitts. The gentleman's time is expired. Mr. Bilirakis. Thank you. Mr. Pitts. The chair recognizes the gentleman from Maryland, Mr. Sarbanes, for 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Sarbanes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I wanted to shift away--we have been talking about sort of in the context of the Medigap policies and so forth--about what you do to address over utilization of procedures and services that may not be as necessary as others on a continuum. I wanted to go to the other side of the spectrum and talk about how reimbursement methodology and the benefits structures can address underutilization of services, particularly on the preventive side, that we would like to see patients take up more, and we have seen some reforms have gotten a lot of attention in the last year or two. Annual wellness visits now are covered without a copayment, so there is no out-of-pocket expense for the patient--certain kinds of screenings, mammography screening, colonoscopy, and so forth. But I wondered if you could just--all the panelists could just speak to that end of the spectrum and some of the innovations you see that really go to this goal of empowering patients to be full partners in their care, which is really talking about how do you boost up the preventive ownership that they have, and also speak to not just the services that get provided that are preventive services, let us say, but some of the new technologies that are being made available that patients can use to better manage their own care on the prevention side and what sort of coverage and benefits do you see coming into the picture there. Ms. Baicker. That is a big and important topic, and I agree with you that sure, payments can influence underutilization. Some services are underutilized because they are underreimbursed but there is a whole world of other behavioral factors beyond payments that affect patient engagement and adherence and management of their diseases, and innovation in provision of those preventive services can range from--there are medicine bottles that now can radio whether the bottle has been opened or not so there can be external monitoring and promotion of adherence. You know whether the patient has actually taken the pill. There are visiting professionals, nurses, other health care providers who can help coordinate care in the home for patients who have trouble getting out of the home or coordinate patient groups, and I think all of those mechanisms for investment in wellness have potential long-term really big positive implications, and the reason we see employers getting involved is that people often have a longer- term relationship with their employer than they do with their insurer and they spend eight-plus hours a day in the workplace, and that is a great site to promote that kind of investment. Ms. Neuman. I am going to talk about prevention in a different sense for an older, frailer population. So there are delivery-system reforms being tested now, for example, the Independence at Home demonstration, where a physician and teams of professionals come into the home with the idea of engaging the patient and family members to prevent patients from needing to go to the emergency room or having to go to the hospital, and they employ technology in the home that can help the medical team and the social services support team monitor what is going on in the home in order to provide care in the most appropriate setting, which in this case is also the lowest cost setting and what patients and their families prefer. So through technology and through a tested intervention of providing team- based care in a home setting, Medicare is exploring the idea of providing better care to people in the most appropriate setting using new technologies and electronic medical records to manage patients better. Mr. Sarbanes. I have recently run into a number of pharmacists and they have sort of raised this issue of how reimbursement works for the services that they assert they are providing that are not covered at all, and that is an example of frontline interaction with patients. It can make a huge difference in a lot of patients who are very dependent on the pharmacist for giving them some guidance. Can you talk about whether there is any look at sort of what the benefit structure and reimbursement is in that arena? Ms. Baicker. So without speaking specifically to pharmacists, I don't know as much about that issue as I would like to, I think having bigger teams of caregivers from doctor to nurse to pharmacist to home visitation would promote looking at sort of the whole patient, that disease management is not about any of the silos, and the siloed reimbursement that we do that underreimburses some and overreimburses others really discourages the team-based approach to being responsible for a group of patients' outcomes among a group of providers that we give some more flexibility and say, here is who would really help this patient, it is this kind of provider. Let us put more resources towards that and let us take resources away from this type of patient. Mr. Sarbanes. Thanks very much. I will yield back. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the chair emeritus of the full committee, Mr. Barton, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Barton. Mr. Chairman, I don't have any questions. I will be happy to yield my time to anybody who wishes it. Mr. Pitts. Mr. Lance? Mr. Lance. Thank you, and good morning to you all. It is a very interesting panel and a very important issue. Some raise concerns about the escalating costs of new medical treatments in the context of the Nation's growing entitlement program costs, and we are all concerned about that obviously. Dr. Baicker, you note in your testimony that technological innovation raises the stakes in this debate. There are different ideological approaches to controlling costs, especially those associated with new treatments. Some choose to develop a framework in the health care reform law whereby the government would choose value rather than the consumer or the patient by implementing the governmentally driven model such as IPAB, and of course, IPAB is something that I oppose and many oppose on a bipartisan basis, particularly here in the House. Could you speak to the value of a cost-sharing framework where Medicare enrollees would choose services and treatments if they were spending their own funds? Ms. Baicker. I agree that the rise in costs raises the stakes in that there are new treatments all the time that could provide really valuable benefits, and there are new ways to spend money that might not provide high health value, and if we were to cover every possible service that might benefit every possible beneficiary even a little bit with public funds, because of innovation, that could be more than 100 percent of GDP. So there has to be some way to allocate those resources, and I would argue that the more flexible that is, the more patients have some choices about the bundle of care that is right for them. I think we can't afford to be subsidizing the use of low-value care for high-income beneficiaries but it is very hard to write down a set of rules that says this is the type of service that is worth it and this isn't. Mr. Lance. Thank you. Would anyone else on the panel like to comment? Dr. Neuman? Ms. Neuman. Well, I would just say it is so hard for patients to make these decisions, particularly when they are sick and they are scared. You know, you think of somebody who has just been diagnosed with some form of cancer and they go to their doctor and their doctor says there are three treatment options for you, and I think you should do this one because I am the expert, and the doctor rarely says that one is going to be the more expensive one and it is a new technology and all that other stuff. When you are scared, you go to the expert and you are rarely thinking about what is the cost to me, I really want to live and survive this disease. Mr. Lance. Thank you. Mr. Miller. Mr. Miller. What we are struggling about is a decision between the locus of decision making and changing the degree to which it currently resides. I think the better way to go is an approach toward more delegated but informed decision making with greater involvement, not maximum involvement, not unrealistic at the beneficiary and consumer level. We need to remember that seniors are allowed to manage the rest of their budgets without Washington telling them what is high value and low value. They have other income that they have to spend on other things and we don't say here is what your benefit structure is for your food, your housing, the other things you are going to spend it on. That can be driven to unrealistic levels, and that is why we have the protections for low-income seniors. The other thing to remember is that the default option often is not to do the most high-level perfectly calibrated value judgments in what we cover. Instead, what we do--and this is the Affordable Care Act--we reduce reimbursement across the board and pretend that we haven't taken away anyone's benefits when we have actually hollowed them out by doing it through the pass-through providers-less. Mr. Lance. I thank you. Let me say that I hope as we move forward, we might review some of the provisions of the Affordable Care Act. Obviously, I did not support it, but moving forward, I hope that we have the opportunity to review, for example, IPAB, and I believe, based on my observation, that there is a bipartisan consensus, particularly here in the House, that we should revisit that issue. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back the balance of my time. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green, for 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for holding the hearing, and I thank our witnesses for appearing. We hear a lot from my colleagues on the Republican side that there needs to be more cost sharing in the Medicare program. Cost sharing makes sense, making sure beneficiaries have skin in the game and good policy. That is why we already do it. Seniors spend a lifetime of working to pay into the system. Once beneficiaries are eligible, they rack up thousands of dollars in bills due to cost sharing. If we continue to decrease the portion paid by the government, more and more future retirees will be unable to pay their bills. With the system remaining solvent until 2026, we have the time to make sure we can do it right. Benefit redesign and more cost shifting to beneficiaries become necessary but the devil is in the details. For instance, we should look at a value-based system and a system where higher-value procedures the government should be willing to pay more for lower-value procedures but beneficiaries should pay more. At the same time, we should focus on strengthening preventive care and improving quality outcomes, which save money now and later. Cost sharing and benefit redesign cannot happen alone, and it must be done carefully, and out-of-pocket expenses must be predictable and necessary health care must be high quality and low cost. Dr. Neuman, is it necessary to approach cost sharing and benefit redesign with nuance, and can you explain in your testimony about the incentivizing adoption of high-value care and what kind of care would be high value? Ms. Neuman. For reasons which you just described, I think it is very important to approach this with nuance. I think we have all three of us talked about the importance of maintaining and improving protections for people with low and modest incomes, and trying to make--adding catastrophic protection but moving together the pieces in between is complicated without shifting costs onto certain people. There seems to be a great deal of interest in moving people toward high-value care but deciding what is high value remains a challenge. So I think I would imagine we would all agree that there are a lot of points of agreement including we should move very carefully given the importance of this program and the protections it provides. Mr. Green. And I do think that even the private sector is moving to that. There was an article just recently about companies, employers coming together and saying in California this is--these are the standard prices and this is what we will pay; now, if you want a higher value, you are on your own, it is out of network so to speak. So maybe the market is actually doing that but it would help the market if we used Medicare because that is our national health care to be able to talk about it. Ms. Baicker. Well, I think it can go both ways. There are times when the market follows Medicare, and this could be a time where Medicare follows the market and learns from the best practices that are already taking place. Mr. Miller. We find that private plans and private markets, because they have to meet a bottom line, they have to satisfy their enrollees, they are in business every day competing with other people, they have to find that high value. They are motivated to do it. It is a lot harder in our system to do this politically. The idea that you are going to be voting every year in Congress on, well, what is the latest set of high-value calculations is not realistic in the same way delegating it to--well, somewhere in HHS and CMS they will figure it out and we will all be happy about that. Again, kind of transcends the bounds of what we have normally seen in the past. Mr. Green. And I agree, and we know when we--a lot of have a change in how medicine is practiced is something we have already--everybody says oh, that is not the way it should be and we are always second-guessing. Dr. Neuman, how has the Affordable Care Act added value to Medicare? Ms. Neuman. Well, in a number of ways. I think one of the clearest ways it has helped is to slow the growth in Medicare spending so it will keep Medicare around for future generations. It will help to sustain the program for longer, and that is probably not something that has gotten a whole of attention. I think also it is putting in place delivery-system reforms to be tested which could have fundamental effect on the future of the delivery of care for maybe current generations but the future generations of Medicare beneficiaries. There are maybe dozens of delivery-system reforms that are being tested. Maybe all of them will not work. But to the extent that any of them are going to improve care and better coordinate care, that will make a fundamental shift. Mr. Green. Well, I know I have only 29 seconds, but the medical-home issue---- Ms. Neuman. Medical home is a good example. There are a number of them. Mr. Green. And also looking at the preventive care, and it just makes so much sense that if you are diabetic to have these annual Medicare exams to make sure. We know also that the lower your income, the less you are likely to go if it costs you money. Ms. Neuman. Exactly, and of course, there is the infamous donut hole which creates enormous problems for people if they have those high expenses, which will now be closed as a result of the Affordable Care Act. Mr. Green. It is closing slower than I would like but it is closing. I yield back my time. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman and now recognizes the gentleman from New York, Mr. Engel, 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Engel. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Let me first say that I would like to see a Medicare benefit structure that protects beneficiaries from catastrophic expenses, encourages the use of high-value services, and strengthens the financial protection for low-income beneficiaries, and having voted against the Ryan budget for the last 3 years, I will not support proposals that seek to cut Medicare benefits or dramatically increase vulnerable beneficiaries' out-of-pocket costs for vital health care services. As we try to transform the health care system into one that promotes prevention and early intervention, I worry, very much worry that proposals that include higher deductible and copayments could be a hindrance to this effort. So Dr. Baicker, I like the example you gave earlier with diabetics. I fear both the human and cost implications if higher cost sharing for doctor's office visits resulted in, for example, a diabetic foregoing regular blood sugar monitoring and that eventually resulted in an expensive hospitalization and debilitating health care requirements. So let me ask you, Dr. Baicker, and also Dr. Neuman, can you elaborate on how increased cost sharing might have a negative impact on treatment adherence? Ms. Baicker. Yes. I think it is important that cost sharing be nuanced, as we all have said, and not crude, and just increasing cost sharing could drive people to forego care that has long-run payoffs, and we want to avoid that. That said, there is a lot of care that has really questionable health benefit that I think our system can't afford to subsidize. So the question is, can we lower the subsidies or increase the cost sharing or prices for care that doesn't produce that downstream benefit and use those resources to shore up services that have really high value, particularly for low-income beneficiaries, and I think it is hard to write down a set of rules that says this yes, this no, but I very much agree with your question that we need to subsidize that kind of care so that people don't forego things that would improve their health. Mr. Engel. Thank you. Dr. Neuman, do you agree? Ms. Neuman. Yes, I do agree. I mean, a very good example is the home health copay or coinsurance, which people have talked about, because Medicare does not apply copayment or coinsurance to these services. So who uses home health services? This is older, frailer women. Many have been to the hospital and are out. So a coinsurance would affect people who have many, many visits and it would probably discourage a lot of visits. Some of them may or may not be necessary but they are visits that have been ordered by a medical professional. So it would clearly either shift costs onto the oldest and frailest and/or reduce utilization, and some people think that is a good idea, but there are risks to doing something like that. The alternative approach is to think about ways of creating incentives for the providers of care to provide appropriate care so that people don't get too much of what they don't need but they get what they do. Mr. Engel. Thank you. I know that studies have looked at the impact of younger populations but I want to ask both of you, do either of you know of studies that have specifically looked at the impact increased cost sharing might have on rates of hospitalization with older and sicker populations like those served by Medicare? Ms. Baicker. There is one study that comes to mind immediately that looked at increasing the cost sharing for pharmaceuticals for a Medicare population that had wraparound coverage in California, and when you increase their copayments for drugs, they took fewer of them, but that was partially then offset by increased hospitalizations downstream and that increase in hospitalizations was concentrated among people who had multiple chronic conditions. It didn't completely offset the cost savings for the reduction in pharmaceutical use but those benefits accrued to different people because there were different insurers involved, so it is a great example of spillovers across silos and the importance of unifying insurance and care. Ms. Engel. Thank you. Dr. Neuman, I agree with your written testimony, the statement in your written testimony that Medicare's current benefit designs are complicated, and for seniors lived on fixed incomes, it can be really difficult for them to accurately budget for health care costs given the various deductibles, premiums, copayments and coinsurance rates in Medicare. In May 2013, just a couple months ago, analysis by your organization, the Kaiser Family Foundation, found that 18 percent of seniors in my home State of New York are living in poverty under the supplemental poverty measure and they just simply cannot afford to pay more. So as we look at benefit redesign, can you elaborate on the benefit you seek to replacing coinsurance rates with copayments? Ms. Neuman. Sure. The supplemental insurance measures higher because it takes into account health expenses, and so that is what people are incurring, which produces larger estimates of seniors in poverty. Copayments can be structured so that they are less onerous, so a great example is back to the home health care we just gave. Coinsurance could be an insurance on every visit which would build up and up and up over time. An alternative would be a copayment on an episode of care which would be fixed, more predictable and wouldn't penalize those who have extensive need for home health services. Mr. Engel. And let me ask you a final question, either one. MedPAC's 2012 recommendations on benefit redesign included the recommendation that the Secretary of Health and Human Services have the authority to make value-based changes to Medicare's benefit design. So can you describe what this might look like with a real-world example, and why this would be of value in our rapidly changing health care system? Ms. Baicker. Sure. So home health, I think, is an interesting example because it is a really important benefit for millions of people but it has been subject to some fairly well publicized overuse, potentially even abuse, of extreme rates of utilization for populations where it might not have such a high benefit. If there were more careful delineation of the cases in which it actually benefited people and they were protected from copayments or had reduced copayments for those cases versus patients where there are lots of alternatives that might do just as well for them and where the utilization is less warranted, you could then ensure that this vital benefit for some is protected by cutting back on overuse in other circumstances. Mr. Engel. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Pitts. The chair thanks the gentleman. That concludes the questions of the members who are present. I am sure there will be more questions from members who are not here, and we will ask them to submit those. We will submit those to you in writing, and we ask the witnesses to please respond promptly. I remind the members that they have 10 business days to submit questions for the record, so they should submit their questions by the close of business on Friday, July 12. We have a unanimous consent request. Mrs. Christensen. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I ask unanimous consent to include in the record the AARP testimony that was given at Ways and Means on the issue of benefit restructuring. Mr. Pitts. Without objection, so ordered. [The information appears at the conclusion of the hearing.] Mr. Pitts. Very, very informational. Thank you very much for your testimony today. And without objection, the subcommittee is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 11:50 a.m., the subcommittee was adjourned.] [Material submitted for inclusion in the record follows:] [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.047 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.048 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.049 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.050 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.051 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.052 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.053 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.054 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.055 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.056 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.057 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.058 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.059 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.060 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.061 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.062 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.063 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.064 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.065 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.066 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.067 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.068 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.069 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.070 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.071 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.072 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.073 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.074 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.075 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.076 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.077 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.078 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.079 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.080 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.081 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.082 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.083 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.084 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.085 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.086 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.087 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.088 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.089 [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] T5449.090