[House Hearing, 113 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] MONETARY POLICY AND THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED THIRTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ JULY 17, 2013 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 113-39 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 82-861 PDF WASHINGTON : 2014 ----------------------------------------------------------------------- For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman GARY G. MILLER, California, Vice MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking Chairman Member SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama, Chairman CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York Emeritus NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York PETER T. KING, New York MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina EDWARD R. ROYCE, California BRAD SHERMAN, California FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West Virginia MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York JOHN CAMPBELL, California STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota DAVID SCOTT, Georgia KEVIN McCARTHY, California AL GREEN, Texas STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri BILL POSEY, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin MICHAEL G. FITZPATRICK, KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota Pennsylvania ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado LYNN A. WESTMORELAND, Georgia JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri GARY C. PETERS, Michigan BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan JOHN C. CARNEY, Jr., Delaware SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin TERRI A. SEWELL, Alabama ROBERT HURT, Virginia BILL FOSTER, Illinois MICHAEL G. GRIMM, New York DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan STEVE STIVERS, Ohio PATRICK MURPHY, Florida STEPHEN LEE FINCHER, Tennessee JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland MARLIN A. STUTZMAN, Indiana KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona MICK MULVANEY, South Carolina JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois DENNY HECK, Washington DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina ANN WAGNER, Missouri ANDY BARR, Kentucky TOM COTTON, Arkansas KEITH J. ROTHFUS, Pennsylvania Shannon McGahn, Staff Director James H. Clinger, Chief Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: July 17, 2013................................................ 1 Appendix: July 17, 2013................................................ 59 WITNESSES Wednesday, July 17, 2013 Bernanke, Hon. Ben S., Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System......................................... 7 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Watt, Hon. Melvin............................................ 60 Bernanke, Hon. Ben S......................................... 61 Additional Material Submitted for the Record Bernanke, Hon. Ben S.: Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, dated July 17, 2013.. 70 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Bachus..................................................... 126 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Kildee..................................................... 132 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Mulvaney................................................... 133 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Pittenger.................................................. 135 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Rothfus.................................................... 138 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Stivers.................................................... 142 MONETARY POLICY AND THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY ---------- Wednesday, July 17, 2013 U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:02 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Jeb Hensarling [chairman of the committee] presiding. Members present: Representatives Hensarling, Miller, Bachus, King, Royce, Lucas, Capito, Garrett, Neugebauer, McHenry, Bachmann, Pearce, Posey, Fitzpatrick, Luetkemeyer, Huizenga, Duffy, Hurt, Stivers, Fincher, Stutzman, Mulvaney, Hultgren, Ross, Pittenger, Wagner, Barr, Cotton, Rothfus; Waters, Maloney, Velazquez, Watt, Sherman, Meeks, Clay, Lynch, Scott, Green, Cleaver, Perlmutter, Himes, Peters, Carney, Sewell, Foster, Kildee, Murphy, Delaney, Beatty, and Heck. Chairman Hensarling. The committee will come to order. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess of the committee at any time. The Chair now recognizes himself for 5 minutes for an opening statement. Chairman Bernanke, welcome. We all know your term as Chairman of the Federal Reserve is up at year's end, and, to paraphrase Twain, we do not know if the rumors of your departure are greatly exaggerated. I will not ask you to comment, but I at least know there is a possibility this could be your last appearance before the committee. I certainly hope it is not. We have other matters to discuss with you and the Fed. But on the off possibility that it is, I did not want to let the moment pass without stating clearly for the record that, as one who has been in public office for 10 years, this chairman considers you to be one of the most able public servants that I have ever met. I suspect that history will record that at a very perilous point in our Nation's economic history, you acted boldly and decisively and creatively, very creatively I might add, and kept your head. And under your leadership, the Fed took a number of actions that certainly staved off an even worse economic event, and for that I believe our Nation will always be grateful. Now, my words are sincere, but they do not negate my concern over the state of the economy today and the role that the Fed is playing in it. In today's semi-annual Humphrey- Hawkins hearing on the state of the economy, we once again face the legacy of the President's economic policies, a failed experiment in fiscal policy that will forever be remembered for its three central pillars: persistent weak economic growth; higher taxes on working families; and unsustainable, record trillion-dollar deficits that one day our children must pay off. Witness the debt clock on either side of the hearing room. The Federal Reserve has, regrettably, in many ways enabled this failed economic policy through a program of risky and unprecedented asset purchases that has swollen its balance sheet by more than $3 trillion. Our committee has an obligation to carefully scrutinize the Federal Reserve's decisions and the way it communicates those decisions to the American people. Chairman Bernanke has correctly observed that credible guidance about the future course of monetary policy is a vital tool that the Fed must use to ensure that markets, consumers, and producers can plan their own economic futures. My constituents back in Texas are concerned about how much they must save for retirement or for their children's college tuition. They are left to wonder how much longer they will have to endure the paltry, paltry returns on the savings created by the Fed's current interest rate policy, which favors borrowers over savers. And yet, recent panicked responses by financial markets to monetary policy communications and observations from a range of economists suggest the Federal Reserve's forward guidance clearly needs some improvement. The market's recent extreme volatility resulting from the offhanded comments of one individual, our witness today, is not healthy for an economy. Again, it indicates a monetary policy guidance system that is not working, and it begs the question: Are current equity market values based upon the fundamentals or unprecedented quantitative easing? Former Fed Chairman William McChesney Martin once observed that the Fed ``should always be engaged in a ruthless examination of its own record.'' Today, we will ask Chairman Bernanke to engage in such a ruthless examination of the Fed's QE exit strategy, which is both untested and clearly not well understood by market participants. Based upon the economy's performance since the Federal Reserve embarked upon its unprecedented campaign of monetary stimulus, many economists have observed, and I would tend to agree, that it is fair to conclude that rarely has so much been spent in pursuit of so little, and rarely has so much been risked in return for so little. The extraordinary measures of 2008 have become the ordinary, albeit unsustainable, measures of 2013 and beyond. Again, as recent events demonstrate, it remains very much an open question whether the Fed can orchestrate an orderly withdrawal of monetary stimulus. Finally, as the Federal Reserve approaches its 100th anniversary later this year, it is incumbent upon this committee to engage in an honest assessment of the Fed's performance and consider just how we can improve the Federal Reserve over the next century. Chairman Bernanke, I appreciate your cooperation with the committee's work. Thank you for being here today. At this time, I will recognize the ranking member for an opening statement. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I would first would like to thank you, Mr. Chairman, for the words in support of Chairman Bernanke's chairmanship. And Chairman Bernanke, I would like to thank you for being with us today. Chairman Bernanke, under your leadership and actions taken by the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the recovery continues to strengthen. Treasury yields and mortgage rates have fallen to their lowest levels in decades, and home values have in turn risen between 5 and 12 percent over the 12-month period ending in April, resulting in a substantial reduction in the number of borrowers with negative equity. Without the dramatic actions you have taken to restore economic growth, the economy simply could not have recovered to the extent it has today. Since your last appearance before this committee to discuss the economy and the outlook for monetary policy back in February, there has been much debate about when and to what extent the FOMC might begin to slow the current pace of asset purchases. As the economic outlook improves, I would urge you not to scale back your monetary stimulus until it is absolutely clear that the now-fragile recovery will hold and real progress has been made in reducing unemployment. Thanks to your efforts, the number of people who are unemployed has steadily fallen since the height of the crisis. However, we still have a long way to go before we have achieved any reasonable measure of full employment. More than 11 million Americans continue to search for work, and countless others have either given up looking altogether or are stuck working fewer hours than they need to get by. With inflation in check, well below the 2 percent target, I would ask that you and your colleagues on the FOMC continue to give the employment aspect of your dual mandate the critical attention it deserves. In addition to the important work you are doing to foster economic growth, the Federal Reserve has also made significant progress in implementing key reforms aimed at strengthening our financial system. In particular, I was very pleased to see-- Chairman Hensarling. Would the gentlelady suspend? Mr. Chairman and the audience, forgive us. As my 9-year old would say, ``Awkward.'' But it appears that the problem has been fixed. If the ranking member wishes to start over, we would-- Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I would like to start over. Chairman Bernanke, under your leadership and through the actions taken by the FOMC, the recovery continues to strengthen. Treasury yields and mortgage rates have fallen to their lowest levels in decades, and home values have in turn risen between 5 and 12 percent over the 12-month period ending in April, resulting in a substantial reduction in the number of borrowers with negative equity. Without the dramatic actions you have taken to spur economic growth, the economy simply could not have recovered to the extent it has today. Since your last appearance before this committee to discuss the economy and the outlook for monetary policy back in February, there has been much debate about when and to what extent the FOMC might be able to slow the current pace of asset purchases. As the economic outlook improves, I would urge you not to scale back your monetary stimulus until it is absolutely clear that the now-fragile recovery will hold and real progress has been made in reducing unemployment. Thanks to your efforts, the number of people who are unemployed has steadily fallen since the height of the crisis. However, we still have a long way to go before we have achieved any reasonable measure of full employment. More than 11 million Americans continue to search for work, and countless others have either given up looking altogether or are stuck working fewer hours than they need to get by. With inflation in check, well below your 2 percent target, I would ask that you and your colleagues on the FOMC continue to give the employment aspect of your dual mandate the critical attention it deserves. In addition to the important work you are doing to foster economic growth, the Federal Reserve has also made significant progress in implementing key reforms aimed at strengthening our financial system. In particular, I was very pleased to see the balanced approach taken by the Federal Reserve in issuing the final Basel III rule, which appropriately takes into account the unique needs of our Nation's community banks. I look forward to your testimony today, and I yield back the balance of my time. And thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The chairman now recognizes the vice chairman of the Monetary Policy and Trade Subcommittee, Mr. Huizenga of Michigan, for 3 minutes. Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Chairman Hensarling, and Ranking Member Waters. I appreciate you holding this hearing today to discuss the semi-annual report on the state of the economy and our fiscal welfare. Additionally, Chairman Bernanke, I do want to thank you for your distinguished service to our country. Certainly, as the Chairman of the Board of Governors over the last 7 years, no one questions your desire to help our country through some of its most difficult times that we have seen in recent history. Today, I am particularly eager to hear your insights on monetary policy and the state of the economy. As I hear from small-business owners across Michigan, and, frankly, being a small-business owner myself in the construction and real estate fields, it is abundantly clear that small businesses are still feeling the negative impacts of the 2008 financial crisis. The economy has been painfully slow to recover--in fact, the weakest of any of the recent recoveries. And, in turn, job creation has lagged. Too many Americans remain out of work, while others have simply stopped looking for work altogether. These are the forgotten casualties that are oftentimes buried in government statistics. I am here to be their voice, and not be a voice of Wall Street but to be a voice for Main Street. Additionally, Washington's addiction to spending remains evident. As we can see up here, we are exceeding $17 trillion in debt, and our chances for recovery as well as the outlook for our children's prosperity dims. For too long, government has in many forms looked upon itself to solve the social and economic ills that our country faces. The Federal Reserve hasn't been any different. Some would argue that may be because of the dual mandate and other things. The Federal Reserve has chosen to implement government- based solutions instead of employing a market-based approach, I would argue, whether it is artificially lowering and sustaining a near-zero interest rate, QE2, Operation Twist, QE3, QE Infinity, as some have quipped about, the government-knows-best approach has only prolonged high levels of unemployment and perpetuated a lack of consumer confidence that has, outside of Wall Street, created an economic environment where investment and growth remain stifled. With our GDP stagnating and unemployment remaining at 7.5 percent or more since President Obama has taken office in 2009, you don't see very many economists predicting the economy to take off in the near future. The policies implemented and prolonged by the Federal Reserve, I believe have worked hand- in-glove with that, and have failed. So when are these failed policies going to come to an end? We know we have had lots of indications. I have already gotten an update from The Wall Street Journal and a number of others who are looking at your comments. But the FOMC says they are planning on keeping the near-zero rate at least until sometime in 2015, with a target of a 6.5 percent unemployment rate. Questions that I think a lot of us have are: At what cost? And if not at what cost, at what benefit? And there are many who look at this analysis and have determined that you are tilting to a ``dovish monetary easing policy,'' away from where we have been going. As a proponent of the free market and reducing the size of government, let me point out that is just one of the many problems with the Administration's policies. Chairman Bernanke, I thank you, and I appreciate, again, your service and I look forward to today's hearing. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Mrs. Maloney, for 2 minutes. Mrs. Maloney. Thank you. I understand this may be Mr. Bernanke's last testimony on Humphrey-Hawkins, as his term expires in January, although I hope it is not--I hope you are reappointed--but I did want to join my colleagues in thanking you for your extraordinary service during one of the most painful periods in the United States' economic history. You have been a creative, innovative leader. The one area where you have always been consistent is you have never been boring. As a former teacher, I appreciate your ability and willingness to explain the Fed's extraordinary measures in clear terms that all Americans can understand. While talk of the Fed's tapering its asset-buying program has dominated the headlines recently, and the United States is still suffering from an unemployment crisis, it was reassuring to read in your prepared testimony that the Fed will continue its asset-buying program as long as economic conditions warrant. So I am glad to see you are shaping Fed policy to help people and not just based on rigid ideological dogma. I also thank you for listening to the concerns in our letter from Chairwoman Capito on the concerns we have for small community and regional banks. We asked you to treat them differently from large international banks, and that is precisely the approach that the Basel III rules took. Community banks did not cause the financial crisis, and I am glad that the Fed came around to seeing our view on this issue. Thank you for your extraordinary service. Chairman Hensarling. The gentlelady yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Ms. Velazquez, for 1\1/2\ minutes. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Welcome, Chairman Bernanke. Thank you for your public service. When I am in my district each week, I hear from people who are truly struggling in the current labor market. Some are unemployed, others are underemployed, and many have stopped looking for work altogether. Adding insult to injury, they hear that the stock market has recently achieved new highs and the housing market is recovering. But for many, this has not translated into new opportunities. Cuts to education and worker retraining programs as well as reduced investment in job-creating infrastructure projects have exacerbated what was an already dire situation. The truth is that it is hard for many to remember that just 6 years ago, the unemployment rate was less than 4.5 percent. And while these are anecdotes, the data shows that they are reflective of the Nation as a whole. Unemployment has remained above 7 percent since December 2008. Gallup is reporting that 17.2 percent of the workforce is underemployed, and the labor participation rate is at a historical low. While the Federal Reserve has a dual mandate, it is this unemployment backdrop that must be given the greatest weight in its deliberations. As the Fed considers when and how to transition away from QE3, it must make certain that it does so without making a challenging employment situation worse. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Watt, for 1\1/2\ minutes. Mr. Watt. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I want to-- Chairman Hensarling. If the gentleman would suspend, if staff would please shut the door? The gentleman is recognized. Mr. Watt. I certainly join in the complimentary statements about the chairman's service. And I have a prepared statement which I will submit for the record, but I thought it might be helpful to just reminisce about some of the changes that this Chairman has made. I was on this committee for a long, long time and never knew where the Federal Reserve was until Chairman Bernanke became the Chairman of the Fed. He opened up the process and demystified what the Fed does. Since that time, we have gone through this whole debate about auditing the Federal Reserve, and substantially more of the records and proceedings of the Federal Reserve are open to the public. He speaks in plain language, as opposed to some of the prior Chairs, who tried to make everything seem so complicated and made it impossible for people to understand, either on the committee or certainly in the public. So I think he has contributed greatly to the image of the Fed, and I just wanted to thank him for his service. I will submit my official statement for the record. Chairman Hensarling. Today, we welcome back to the committee, in the words of the gentlelady from New York, the never-boring, Honorable Ben Bernanke, Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. I believe we all agree he needs no further introduction, so he will not receive one. I do wish to all Members that the Chairman will be excused promptly at 1:00 p.m. And I wish to inform Members on the Majority side that those who were not able to ask questions during the Chairman's last appearance will be given priority today. Without objection, Chairman Bernanke, your written statement will be made a part of the record. So, you are now recognized for your oral presentation. STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE BEN S. BERNANKE, CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling, Ranking Member Waters, and other members of the committee, I am pleased to present the Federal Reserve's semi-annual ``Monetary Policy Report to the Congress.'' I will discuss current economic conditions and the outlook and then turn to monetary policy, and I will finish with a short summary of our ongoing work on regulatory reform. The economic recovery has continued at a moderate pace in recent quarters, despite strong headwinds created by Federal fiscal policy. Housing has contributed significantly to recent gains in economic activity. Home sales, house prices, and residential construction have moved up over the past year, supported by local interest rates and improved confidence in both the housing market and the economy. Rising housing construction and home sales are adding to job growth, and substantial increases in home prices are bolstering household finances and consumer spending while reducing the number of homeowners with underwater mortgages. Housing activity and prices seem likely to continue to recover notwithstanding the recent increases in mortgage rates, but it will be important to monitor developments in this sector carefully. Conditions in the labor market are improving gradually, yet the unemployment rate stood at 7.6 percent in June, about a half percentage point lower than in the months before the Federal Open Market Committee initiated its current asset purchase program in September. Nonfarm payroll employment has increased by an average of about 200,000 jobs per month so far this year. Despite these gains, the job situation is far from satisfactory, as the unemployment rate remains well above its longer-run normal level and rates of underemployment and long- term unemployment are still much too high. Meanwhile, consumer price inflation has been running below the committee's longer-run objective of 2 percent. The price index for personal consumption expenditures rose only 1 percent over the year ending in May. This softness reflects, in part, some factors that are likely to be transitory. Moreover, measures of longer-term inflation expectations have generally remained stable, which should help move inflation back up toward 2 percent. However, the committee is certainly aware that very low inflation poses risks to economic performance--for example, by raising the real cost of capital investment--and increases the risk of outright deflation. Consequently, we will monitor this situation closely, as well, and we will act as needed to ensure that inflation moves back toward our 2 percent objective over time. At the June FOMC meeting, my colleagues and I projected that economic growth would pick up in the coming quarters, resulting in gradual progress toward the level of unemployment and inflation consistent with the Federal Reserve's statutory mandate to foster maximum employment and price stability. Specifically, most participants saw real GDP growth beginning to step up during the second half of this year, eventually reaching a pace between 2.9 and 3.6 percent in 2015. They projected the unemployment rate to decline to between 5.8 and 6.2 percent by the final quarter of 2015, and they saw inflation gradually increasing toward the committee's 2 percent objective. The pickup in economic growth predicted by most committee participants partly reflects their view that Federal fiscal policy will exert somewhat less drag over time, as the effects of the tax increases and the spending sequestration diminish. The committee also believes that risks to the economy have diminished since the fall, reflecting some easing of the financial stresses in Europe; the gains in housing and labor markets that I mentioned earlier; the better budgetary positions of State and local governments; and stronger household and business balance sheets. That said, the risks remain that tight Federal fiscal policy will restrain economic growth over the next few quarters by more than we currently expect or that the debate concerning other fiscal policy issues, such as the status of the debt ceiling, will evolve in a way that could hamper the recovery. More generally, with the recovery still proceeding at only a moderate pace, the economy remains vulnerable to unanticipated shocks, including the possibility that global economic growth may be slower than currently anticipated. With unemployment still high and declining only gradually and with inflation running below the committee's longer-run objective, a highly accommodative monetary policy will remain appropriate for the foreseeable future. In normal circumstances, the committee's basic tool to provide monetary accommodation is its target for the Federal funds rate. However, the target range for the Federal funds rate has been close to zero since late 2008 and cannot be reduced meaningfully further. Instead, we are providing additional policy accommodation through two distinct yet complementary policy tools. The first tool is expanding the Federal Reserve's portfolio of longer- term Treasury securities and agency mortgage-backed securities. We are currently purchasing $40 billion per month in agency MBS and $45 billion per month in Treasurys. The second tool is forward guidance about the committee's plans for setting the Federal funds rate target over the medium term. Within our overall policy framework, we think of these tools as having somewhat different roles. We are using asset purchases and the resulting expansion in the Federal Reserves's balance sheet primarily to increase the near-term momentum of the economy, with the specific goal of achieving a substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market in a context of price stability. We have made some progress toward this goal, and, with inflation subdued, we intend to continue our purchases until a substantial improvement in the labor market outlook has been realized. In addition, even after purchases end, the Federal Reserve will be holding its stock of Treasury and agency securities off the market and reinvesting the proceeds from maturing securities, which will continue to put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, support mortgage markets, and help to make broader financial conditions more accommodative. We are relying on near-zero short-term interest rates, together with our forward guidance that rates will continue to be exceptionally low--this is our second tool--to help maintain a high degree of monetary accommodation for an extended period after asset purchases end, even as the economic recovery strengthens and unemployment declines toward more normal levels. In appropriate combination, these two tools can provide the high level of policy accommodation needed to promote a stronger economic recovery with price stability. In the interest of transparency, the committee participants agreed in June that it would be helpful to lay out more details about our thinking regarding the asset purchase program-- specifically, provide additional information on our assessment of progress to date as well as the likely trajectory of the program if the economy evolves as projected. This agreement to provide additional information did not reflect a change in policy. The committee's decisions regarding the asset purchase program and the overall stance of monetary policy depend on our assessment of the economic outlook and of the cumulative progress toward our objectives. Of course, economic forecasts must be revised when new information arrives and are, thus, necessarily provisional. As I noted, the economic outcomes that the committee participants saw as most likely in their June projections involved continuing gains in labor markets, supported by moderate growth that picks up over the next several quarters as the restraint from fiscal policy diminishes. The committee participants also saw inflation moving back toward our 2 percent objective over time. If the incoming data were to be broadly consistent with these projections, we anticipated that it would be appropriate to moderate the monthly pace of purchases later this year. And if the subsequent data continued to confirm this pattern of ongoing economic improvement and normalizing inflation, we expected to continue to reduce the pace of purchases in measured steps through the first half of next year, ending then around midyear. At that point, if the economy had evolved along the lines we anticipated, the recovery would have gained further momentum, unemployment would be in the vicinity of 7 percent, and inflation would be moving toward our 2 percent objective. Such outcomes would be fully consistent with the goals of the asset purchase program that we established in September. I emphasize that, because our asset purchases depend on economic and financial developments, they are by no means on a preset course. On the one hand, if economic conditions were to improve faster than expected and inflation appeared to be rising decisively back toward our objective, the pace of asset purchases could be reduced somewhat more quickly. On the other hand, if the outlook for employment were to become relatively less favorable, if inflation did not appear to be moving back toward 2 percent, or if financial conditions, which have tightened recently, were judged to be insufficiently accommodative to allow us to attain our mandated objectives, the current pace of purchases could be maintained for longer. Indeed, if needed, the committee would be prepared to employ all of its tools, including an increase in the pace of purchases for a time, to promote a return to maximum employment in the context of price stability. As I noted, the second tool the committee is using to support the recovery is forward guidance regarding the path of the Federal funds rate. The committee has said that it intends to maintain a high degree of monetary accommodation for a considerable time after the asset purchase program ends and the economic recovery strengthens. In particular, the committee anticipates that its current exceptionally low target range for the Federal funds rate will be appropriate at least as long as the unemployment rate remains above 6.5 percent and inflation expectations remain well-behaved in the sense described in the FOMC's statement. As I have observed on several occasions, the phrase, ``at least as long as,'' is a key component of the rate policy guidance. These words indicate that the specific numbers for unemployment and inflation in the guidance are thresholds, not triggers. Reaching one of the thresholds would not automatically result in an increase in the Federal funds rate target. Rather, it would lead the committee to consider whether the outlook for the labor market, inflation, and the broader economy justifies such an increase. For example, if a substantial part of the reductions in measured unemployment were judged to reflect cyclical declines in labor force participation rather than gains in employment, the committee would be unlikely to view a decline of unemployment to 6.5 percent as a sufficient reason to raise its target for the Federal funds rate. Likewise, the committee would be unlikely to raise the funds rate if inflation remained persistently below our longer-run objective. Moreover, so long as the economy remains short of maximum employment, inflation remains near our longer-run objective, and inflation expectations remain well-anchored, increases in the target for the Federal funds rate, once they begin, are likely to be gradual. I will finish by providing you with a brief update on progress on reforms to reduce the systemic risk of the largest financial firms. As Governor Tarullo discussed in his testimony last week before the Senate Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs Committee, the Federal Reserve, with the other Federal banking agencies, adopted a final rule earlier this month to implement the Basel III capital reforms. The final rule increases the quality and quantity of required regulatory capital by establishing a new minimum common equity Tier 1 capital ratio and implementing a capital conservation buffer. The rule also contains a supplementary leverage ratio and a countercyclical capital buffer that apply only to large and internationally active banking organizations, consistent with their systemic importance. In addition, the Federal Reserve will propose capital surcharges on firms that pose the greatest systemic risk and will issue a proposal to implement the Basel III quantitative liquidity requirements as they are phased in over the next few years. The Federal Reserve is considering further measures to strengthen the capital positions of large, internationally active banks, including the proposed rule issued last week that would increase the required leverage ratios of such firms. The Fed also is working to finalize the enhanced prudential standards set out in Sections 165 and 166 of the Dodd-Frank Act. Among these standards, rules relating to stress-testing and resolution planning already are in place, and we have been actively engaged in stress tests and reviewing the first wave of resolution plans. In coordination with other agencies, we have made significant progress on the key substantive issues relating to the Volcker Rule and are hoping to complete it by year end. Finally, the Federal Reserve is preparing to regulate and supervise systemically important nonbank financial firms. Last week, the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) designated two nonbank financial firms. It has proposed the designation of a third firm, which has requested a hearing before the Council. We are developing a supervisory and regulatory framework that can be tailored to each firm's business mix, risk profile, and systemic footprint, consistent with the Collins amendment and other legal requirements under the Dodd-Frank Act. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would be pleased to take questions. [The prepared statement of Chairman Bernanke can be found on page 61 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chair will recognize himself for 5 minutes for questions. Mr. Chairman, the first question is probably, in some respects, the most obvious question. You are aware better than most that, as you testified before the Joint Economic Committee on May 22nd, as The Wall Street Journal reports, the stock market ``moved up when Mr. Bernanke's congressional testimony was released in the morning, near-triple-digit gains when he began taking questions, turned negative when the minutes were released.'' On June 19th, at the mere hint of tapering, the Dow Jones dropped almost 600 points in 2 days. And then recently, your comments on July 10th have seen the S&P hit record highs. A couple of questions result from this--a couple of quotes, first. Warren Buffett has described our stock market as waiting ``on a hair trigger'' from the Fed. Dallas Fed President Richard Fisher describes stock markets as ``hooked on the drug'' of easy money. You have described your thresholds as providing guidance to the market, but you have also qualified that the thresholds provide no guidance as to when or how the policy will change once those thresholds have been reached. A recent survey of 55 economists by The Wall Street Journal gives the Fed a D-minus for its guidance. So can you comment on your guidance, and can you comment on Mr. Buffett's and President Fisher's comments? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly, Mr. Chairman. We are in a difficult environment economically, financially, and, of course, we are dealing with unprecedented monetary policy developments. I continue to believe that we should do everything we can to apprise the markets and the public about our plans and how we expect to move forward with monetary policy. I think not speaking about these issues would risk a dislocation, a moving of market expectations away from the expectations of the committee. It would have risked increased buildup of leverage for excessively risky positions in the market, which I believe the unwinding of that is part of the reason for some of the volatility that we have seen. And so I think it has been very important that we communicate as best we can what our plans and our thinking is. I think the markets are beginning to understand our message, and that volatility has obviously moderated. Chairman Hensarling. I hope you are right. Let me change subjects. This committee tomorrow will have a hearing on a bill designed to reform Fannie and Freddie. The FHA put us on a path toward a sustainable housing policy in America. The Fed, a number of years ago, released a study that estimated that Fannie and Freddie passed on a mere 7 basis points subsidy in their interest rates. That was by economists Passmore, Sherlund, and Burgess. Does the Fed still stand by that study? Mr. Bernanke. It was a good study, yes. Chairman Hensarling. You have been quoted in the past with respect to the GSEs, stating, ``Privatization would solve several problems associated with the current GSE model. It would eliminate the conflict between private shareholders and public policy and likely diminish the systemic risk, as well. Other benefits are that private entities presumably would be more innovative and efficient than a government agency, in that they could operate with less interference from political interests.'' Do you still stand by that statement? Mr. Bernanke. I stand by the view that the GSEs, as constituted before the crisis, had very serious flaws in terms of the implicit guarantee from the government that was not compensated, the lack of capital, and the fact that they were torn between public and private purposes. So I agree that the GSEs were a significant problem. Chairman Hensarling. Let me ask you about another one of your statements. In 2008, you observed, ``GSE-type organizations are not essential to successful mortgage financing. Indeed, many other industrial countries without GSEs have achieved homeownership rates comparable to that of the United States. One device that has been widely used is covered bonds.'' Do you still stand by that statement? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Chairman Hensarling. Now, as I understand it, you do believe that it is advisable to retain some type of government backstop in times of great turmoil, as we saw in 2008. The Fed, I believe, has put forth its own plan; is that correct? Mr. Bernanke. No, the Fed hasn't put forth a plan. Chairman Hensarling. Maybe it is Federal Reserve economists Hancock and Passmore? Mr. Bernanke. That would be an independent piece of research that is not endorsed by the Board of Governors. Chairman Hensarling. Okay. Regrettably, I see my time has come to an end. The Chair now recognizes the ranking member for 5 minutes. Ms. Waters. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, I am interested in the survey that was done by the IMF where they reported that the United States could spur growth by adopting a more balanced and gradual pace of fiscal consolidation, especially at a time when monetary policy has limited room to support the recovery further. Specifically, the IMF recommended that Congress repeal the sequester, raise the debt ceiling to avoid any severe shocks, and adopt a comprehensive, backloaded set of measures to restore long-run fiscal sustainability. Would you agree with the IMF's conclusion that the austerity policies currently in place have significantly depressed growth in the United States? And to what extent can monetary policy offset the adverse consequences of the current contractual fiscal policy? Mr. Bernanke. As I have said many times, I think that fiscal policy is focusing a bit too much on the short run, and not enough on the long run. The near-term policies, which include not only the sequester but the tax increases and other measures, according to the CBO, are cutting about a percentage point and a half, about 1.5 percentage points from growth in 2013. That would mean, instead of 2 percent growth, we might be enjoying 3.5 percent growth. At the same time, Congress has not addressed a lot of long-run issues, where sustainability remains not yet achieved. So, yes, my suggestion to Congress is to consider possibilities that involve somewhat less restraint in the near term and more action to make sure that we are on a sustainable path in the long run. And I think that is broadly consistent with the IMF's perspective. Ms. Waters. I would like to ask you a question about housing finance, since the chairman mentioned that we will be meeting to hear about his bill that, among other things, winds down the GSEs and effectively ends the government's guarantee. While I support reducing the current government footprint in the housing market, I am concerned that such a drastic reduction will adversely affect homeowners, depress the broader economy, and eliminate the 30-year, fixed-rate mortgage as we know it. How might ending the 30-year, fixed-rate mortgage affect access to affordable mortgage credit, the housing markets generally, and the Fed's need to continue its extraordinary support of the housing market through quantitative easing? Mr. Bernanke. I think it is very important that average people in America have access to mortgage credit which allows them to buy a home if that is what their financial situation and their needs require. As long as the product is consumer- friendly, consumer-safe, protected in that respect, and is financially affordable, I don't think it necessarily has to be in a specific form. I think there are different ways. Many people use different types of mortgage structures. I think the main thing, again, it is not the instrument itself but, rather, the access of the average American to homeownership and to mortgage credit. Ms. Waters. To what extent is the structure of a country's housing finance system a prime contributor to macroeconomic volatility? Would you agree that housing finance systems with variable-rate mortgages are the dominant product and more vulnerable to extreme bubble-bust cycles in the housing market? Mr. Bernanke. That is a good question. I haven't really seen evidence on that. In the United States, unfortunately, adjustable-rate mortgages were often sold to people who weren't really able to manage the higher payments when the payments rose, and they weren't very well disclosed. There are other countries that have adjustable-rate mortgages where they haven't had quite the same problems. And I guess one small advantage is that when the central bank changes interest rates, it shows up immediately in costs of housing, and may be more powerful in that respect. But I think the most important issue is disclosure and underwriting, making sure that people can afford the costs of the mortgage even when the payments go up. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much. I appreciate your comments about the different types of structures. And I suppose your comments about variable-rate mortgages are probably consistent with concerns we have about no-documentation loans and other kinds of things where we know we can't guarantee that those people taking out the mortgages are able to repay them. Mr. Bernanke. Was there a question? Sorry. I can't hear very well. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Huizenga, for 5 minutes. Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, Mr. Chairman, I want to quickly cover three areas: one, talk a little bit about interest rates; two, talk about too-big-to-fail; and three, briefly talk about the Taylor Rule. Now, I would be reticent if I didn't pass along a question one of my friends had: Should he refinance right now? I think that is probably a question a lot of people have. I know I did, not that long ago. You may answer if you would like. Mr. Bernanke. I am not a qualified financial advisor. Mr. Huizenga. That would be part of the problem with Dodd- Frank. If you don't qualify, then nobody qualifies. But I think there is that fear out there, with the increase in mortgage interest rates. A lot of us, me coming out of a real estate background, I think a lot of us finally said, maybe we should be watching what your comments were going to be and maybe get clued in. But what I am really concerned about is that--and this is at some risk to myself of maybe not having a very warm welcome next time I am up in New York City visiting some of my friends up there. But I am concerned that Wall Street is too dependent on the Fed and sort of the signals that you are having, while Main Street is really getting buffeted about, whether it is interest rates, tax policy, certainly regulatory policy as well. And we need to make sure that we are moving beyond that. I am sure, who knows, maybe the market just took an uptick based on my comments. Or maybe they took a downtick; who knows. We know that they are going to be following your comments much more closely. But we have to make sure that this is about Main Street, not about Wall Street, and how this is going to be affecting people back home. On too-big-to-fail, we had a hearing last week regarding too-big-to-fail, and President Lacker from the Federal Reserve in Richmond testified about the new restrictions in Dodd-Frank imposed on Section 13.3 of the Federal Reserve Act, an emergency provision the Fed used to bail AIG out at the time. And he said, ``I think it is an open question as to how constraining it is. It says it has to be a program of market- based access, but it doesn't say that more than one firm has to show up to use it. But it certainly seems conceivable to me that a program could be designed that essentially is only availed of by one firm.'' Now, do you agree with President Lacker and the new restrictions added in 13.3 will not be effective in limiting the Fed's freedom to carry out future bailouts? Or even if it did, would you have the authority to enforce those limitations? Mr. Bernanke. So, on your first point, I just want to emphasize that we are very focused on Main Street. We are trying to create jobs, we are trying to make housing affordable. Our low interest rates have created a lot of ability to buy automobiles. Mr. Huizenga. Is it fair to say, though, that Wall Street has benefited more than Main Street has? Mr. Bernanke. I don't think so. We are working through the mechanisms we have, which, of course, are financial interest rates and financial asset prices. But our goals are Main Street, our goals are jobs, our goals are low inflation. And I think we have had not all the success we would like, but we have had some success. I would like to respond to your second one, though, from President Lacker. Mr. Huizenga. Yes. Mr. Bernanke. I don't think that 13.3, as significantly modified by Dodd-Frank, could be used to bail out an individual firm. According to Dodd-Frank, 13.3 has to be a broadly based program. It has to be open to a wide variety of firms within a category. It cannot be used to lend to an insolvent firm. It requires both the approval of the Board and of the Secretary of the Treasury to be used. And it must be immediately communicated to the Congress. I do not think that 13.3 could be used in that way. Mr. Huizenga. Obviously, there may be some disagreement within your organization, but I would love to work with you on trying to tighten that up. The other item, very quickly, in our last minute here, on the Taylor Rule. A recent survey of 55 economists by The Wall Street Journal gave the Federal Reserve a grade of D-minus for its guidance. Now, I would hate to see what it had been previously, 10 years ago, let's say. But do you believe that these facts indicate a monetary policy guidance function that needs more work? Mr. Bernanke. I don't know what the grade refers to. It could be the fact that there are many different voices at the Fed. There are a lot of different views. And I think there is a benefit to having a lot of different views. People can hear the debate. On the other hand, if people are looking for a single signal, it can be a little confusing. I think we are doing a reasonable job of communicating our intentions and our plans in the context of a complex monetary policy strategy. Mr. Huizenga. I'm sorry, I have 10 seconds, and so I will make it more of a statement, but I would love to follow up with you in writing. I think many of us are concerned that when you rolled the threshold guidance out, you described it as Taylor Rule-like, but many of us are afraid that it may not have as much similarity to a rules-based approach. And I look forward to working with you on that. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Clay, the ranking member of the Monetary Policy Subcommittee. Mr. Clay. Thank you, Chairman Hensarling. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here. As you know, the unemployment rate is 7.60 percent. The economy added a little over 200,000 jobs per month for the first 6 months of this year. In 2012, we averaged about 180,000 jobs per month. This is a slight increase. And the private sector, I would say, added most of the jobs. Under the sequester, State and Federal Governments have lost jobs. Any forecast on, if the sequester stays in place, what the condition of the economy will be in the next year or so? Mr. Bernanke. The first observation which you made, which is quite right, is that in this recovery, even as the private sector has been creating jobs, governments at all levels have cut something on the order of 600,000 jobs. In previous recoveries, usually the government sector was adding jobs. So that is one reason why the recovery has been slow. Again, this year, the best estimate I have is the CBO's estimate at 1.5 percentage points on growth this year. I can't say we are certain about how long those effects will last, but our anticipation is that later this year and into next year, as those effects become less restrictive, that the economy will begin to pick up, and we will see some benefits from that. But of course that hasn't happened yet, and we have to keep monitoring that. Mr. Clay. Shifting to the housing market, which has been a drag on the economy for the last couple of years, it has recently begun to show signs of turning around. Do you believe the increase in housing prices provide evidence that the Fed's monetary policy is working, and is there a causal or correlative relationship between the two? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, I think so. Historically, the two areas of the economy which have been most impacted by monetary policy are housing and autos, and those are two of the areas right now which are leading our recovery. And evidently low mortgage rates have contributed, household formation and other factors have also contributed, but the housing sector is certainly an important component of the recovery at this point. And housing prices going up are not only beneficial in terms of stimulating more construction, but they also improve the balance sheets of households and make them more confident, more willing to spend on other goods and services. Mr. Clay. And so you are not concerned that recent increases in mortgage rates could jeopardize the fragile housing recovery? Mr. Bernanke. The mortgage rates remain relatively low, but they are higher than they were, and we do have to monitor that. Mr. Clay. And they are inching up. Mr. Bernanke. We will see how they evolve, but we do have to monitor that, and we will see how housing and house prices go from here. Mr. Clay. Do you believe the labor market in which the unemployment rate hovers just below 8 percent reflects a new normal, as some have suggested? What is a sustainable rate of unemployment, in your view, over the medium and long term? And what, in your view, could be done to strengthen the aspect of the labor force beyond the rate of employment, including wages, hours worked, and labor force participation? Mr. Bernanke. No. I think we are still far above the longer-run normal unemployment rate. To give you one illustration, the projections of the participants of the FOMC suggests that the long-run unemployment rate might be closer to 5.2 to 6 percent, but even beyond that, that amount of unemployment reflects the fact that there are people who don't have the right skills for the available jobs, who are located in the wrong parts of the country. So training, education, improving the functioning of the labor market, improving matching, there are things that can be done through labor policy, labor force policy, that could even lower unemployment further than the Fed can through just increasing demand. Mr. Clay. So say, for instance, in the African-American community where male unemployment hovers around 13 or 14 percent, do you think the Labor Department and community colleges and others need to do a better job of connecting job training to targeted growth industries? Mr. Bernanke. I have seen some very good programs where employers, community colleges, and State governments work together to try to link up people with jobs, and the community college provides the right training. Mr. Clay. My time is up. I thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Alabama, the chairman emeritus of our committee, Mr. Bachus. Mr. Bachus. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, I have not seen a lot of discussion concerning the reduction in Treasury issuance with the deficit coming down. It seems like that would give you more latitude to reduce your purchases of Treasurys. Would you like to comment on that? Mr. Bernanke. The Fed still owns a relatively small share of all the Treasurys outstanding. It is true that as the new issuance comes down, our purchases become a larger share of the new flow of Treasurys coming into the market. But we have not seen that our purchases are disrupting the Treasury market in any way, and we believe that they have been effective in keeping interest rates low. That being said, as I have described, depending on how the economy evolves, we are considering changing the mix of tools that we use to maintain the high level of accommodation. Mr. Bachus. Yes, but the fact that they probably will be issuing less is, I think, a factor that you would consider. Mr. Bernanke. We would consider that, but our view is that what matters is the share of the total that we own, not the share of the new issuance. Mr. Bachus. All right. Chairman Bernanke, you mentioned last year in Jackson Hole that you viewed unemployment as cyclical. Do you still believe that it is cyclical and not structural? Mr. Bernanke. Just like my answer a moment ago, I think that probably about 2 percentage points or so, say the difference between 7.6 and 5.6 percent, is cyclical, and the rest of it is what economists would call frictional or structural. Mr. Bachus. Have you done any studies--do you think maybe 5 percent structural and 2 percent cyclical? Mr. Bernanke. Most importantly, so far we don't see much evidence that the structural component of unemployment has increased very much during this period. It is something we have been worried about, because with people unemployed for a year or 2 years or 3 years, they lose their skills, they lose their attachment to the labor market, and the concern is they will become unemployable. So far it still appears to us that we can attain an unemployment rate--we, the country, can attain an unemployment rate somewhere in the 5s. Mr. Bachus. Again, the most recent FOMC minutes didn't specifically address the 7 percent unemployment target, but you mentioned it in your press conference after that. Was that 7 percent target discussed and agreed on in the meeting? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, it was. Seven percent is not a target. It was intended to be indicative of the amount of improvement we want to see in the labor market. So I described a series of conditions that would need to be met for us to proceed with our moderation of purchases. We have a go-around where everybody in the committee, including those who are not voting, get to express their general views, and there was good support for both the broad plan, which I described, and for the use of 7 percent as indicative of the kind of improvement we are trying to get. Mr. Bachus. Okay. Thank you. The FOMC participants have stated, some of them, that their assessment of the longer-run normal level of the Fed funds rate has been lowered. Do you agree with that? Mr. Bernanke. A rough rule of thumb is that long-term interest rates are roughly equal to the inflation rate plus the growth rate of the economy. The inflation rate, we are looking to get to 2 percent. To the extent that in the aftermath of the crisis and from other reasons that the economy had a somewhat lower real growth rate going forward, that would imply a lower equilibrium interest rate as well. Mr. Bachus. Okay. You mentioned--GDP estimates also come in. They were too optimistic. Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Bachus. I think you said earlier you believe one factor is the policy decisions made by Congress to a certain extent, the sequester, and failing to address the long-term structural changes in the entitlement programs. Mr. Bernanke. That is right, although I should say that we all should keep in mind that these are very rough estimates, and they get revised. For example, you get somewhat different numbers when you look at gross domestic income instead of gross domestic product. But, yes, as I have said a couple of times already, I think that Congress would be well-advised to focus more on the longer term. Mr. Bachus. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Mrs. Maloney. Mrs. Maloney. It is my understanding that we are going to people who did not have the opportunity to ask questions at the last hearing, so the next person would be Mr. Perlmutter. Ms. Waters. Mr. Perlmutter was next on the list, not Mrs. Maloney, so would you please call-- Chairman Hensarling. I am happy to do it. It is just the list that we received from you, but we are very happy to recognize the gentleman from Colorado for 5 minutes. Mr. Perlmutter. Sure you are. I thank the Chair, and I thank the gentlelady from New York. Mr. Chairman, it is good to see you. As always, I think--I just want to compliment you on being a steady hand through all of this. In terms of fiscal policy, we had a very expansionary policy, and now we have had a very contractionary policy. And to sort of piggyback a little bit on Mr. Bachus' question and Mr. Clay's, and I am looking at page 11 of your report where it says, ``The Congressional Budget Office estimated that the deficit-reduction policies in current law generating the 2\1/4\ percentage point narrowing in the structural deficit will also restrain the pace of real GDP growth by 1\1/2\ percentage points this calendar year, relative to what it would have been otherwise.'' What does 1\1/2\ percent of real GDP mean in terms of jobs and wealth? And, 1\1/2\ percent is just a number. What is that? Mr. Bernanke. It is very significant. The CBO also estimated that 1\1/2\ percentage points was something on the order of 750,000 full-time equivalent jobs. I think with another 1\1/2\ percentage point of growth, we would see probably unemployment down another 7- or 8/10, something like that. So it makes a very big difference. It is very substantial. Now, again, we are hoping that as the economy moves through this period, we will begin to see more rapid growth later this year and into next year. Mr. Perlmutter. Okay. So let us talk about--you have a graph, and I don't know if you have your report in front of you, but the graph on the preceding page, 10, graph A, Total and Structural Federal Budget Deficit 1980 to 2018. Do you see that? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Perlmutter. Can you explain that graph? It looks to me like at some point there isn't--you project or there is a projection here of no structural deficit in about 2017, 2018. What does that mean? Mr. Bernanke. That means taking away the effects of the business cycle. The business cycle causes extra deficit, because with the economy weak, you get less tax revenue. You have more spending on social programs of various kinds. What that is saying is that if we were at full employment, that in 2015, I believe it is, the structural deficit would be close to zero. That is the CBO estimate. Mr. Perlmutter. Okay. I now kind of want to turn to some other questions, if I could. Mr. Huizenga and Mr. Clay were also asking you about interest rates, and you said we are at historically low interest rates. I would recommend to you, and you probably already know about, an app that you guys have that I can get on my iPad. It is called The Economy, and it shows-- this one shows how we have been doing over the last 40 years. And we are--it was way up here in, like, 1980 at about 18 percent, and then way down here at about 3.3 percent about 2 months ago. And so we have come way down, except that in the last 2 months--see, what is good about this app, you can also do it on a 1-year basis. And on a 1-year basis, it shows that from April 2013 to the end of June, we went about straight up, about 33 percent increase in interest rates, which was from 3.3 percent to about 4.5 percent. Mr. Bernanke. You are talking about mortgages now? Mr. Perlmutter. Mortgage rates, yes, sir. So how does that come about? Mr. Bernanke. There will be three reasons for it. The first is that the economic news has been a little better. For example, there was a pretty strong labor market report that caused yields to go up as investors became more optimistic. A second factor is probably that some excessively risky or leveraged positions unwound in the last month or two as the Federal Reserve communicated about policy plans. The tightening associated with that is unwelcome, but on the other hand, at least there is the benefit of maybe perhaps reducing some of those positions in the market. Mr. Perlmutter. The concern I have, and I think it was expressed by both Mr. Huizenga and Mr. Clay, is that one of the underpinnings of this recovery, you said, is that now housing is beginning to get much stronger. It was historically so weak, but this kind of increase, if it continues, is going to slow that down. Wouldn't you agree? Mr. Bernanke. I agree that we need accommodative monetary policy for the foreseeable future, and I have said that. Mr. Perlmutter. Thank you. And I thank the Chair. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Miller, for 5 minutes. Mr. Miller. Mr. Bernanke, welcome. I want to thank you for listening to us. On the recent ruling on Basel III, you acknowledge insurance companies are very different from banks, and you postponed any negative decision on that. I think that was a very, very wise move. You are probably aware that the committee is about to consider a housing finance reform bill. I have looked at the GSEs in the past, and I have always had a problem with the way they were fundamentally flawed. You had a hybrid situation where the private sector made all the profits, and the taxpayers took all the risk, which was problematic from the beginning. You can go back to a time when you could say they performed their function very well, but they created major problems. In recent years, they didn't adhere to underwriting standards. They were buying predatory loans rather than conforming loans. They were chasing the market rather than playing a countercyclical role, and that has been very problematic. Now we look at a situation and say, what do we do and where do we go? And if the United States were to end the function of the GSEs as it applies to conforming loans, would the private market be able to provide liquidity to the market? And the second part of that is, what about the time of crisis? Would investors be there to purchase mortgage-backed securities, and would interest rates tend to rise in that type of situation? Mr. Bernanke. Let me first say that I agree with your analysis of GSEs. And the Fed for many years was warning about lack of capital, the implicit guarantee, the conflict between public and private motives, and so we agree that is something that needs to be fixed. There are a number of plans out there for reform. I think everyone agrees that one of the key questions is what role, if any, the government should play. It seems pretty clear that the private sector should be playing more of a role than it is now. Right now, we have basically a government-run mortgage securitization market, but in order to protect the taxpayer, to increase efficiency, to allow for more product innovation and so on, we would like to have more market participation. But, again, the question is what role should the government play? I don't know the answer to that, but I would say that, first, if the government does play a role, it should be fairly compensated; that is, instead of having an implicit guarantee that it ended up having to make good on, like the FDIC or some other similar institution, it should receive some kind of insurance premium. Mr. Miller. And I think that is important, because I have argued for a position where if you are going to have a conduit, let us say a facility to replace the GSEs, then the profits from the g-fees should go into a reserve account to make sure that is solvent. And then if you have a reinsurance fee when the mortgage-backed security is sold, that should also go in a reserve account. And when the account goes up large enough over 7 or 8 years, there is no need for a government guarantee, because the reserves will be so huge based on the profits that they would turn, based on what they historically have done, you wouldn't put the taxpayer at risk. But the problem we have had in the past, and I have always had a problem with it, is when you have investors investing in GSEs, the GSEs at that point in time chase market share to make investors happy. That is not their role. Their role is to be countercyclical. But I am also concerned that if we make a mistake, the government is still going to be there on the hook, because they are not going to let the housing market crumble if something goes wrong. So if you don't have some entity that is self- sufficient, has huge capital to make sure that it can withstand a downturn, we are going to end up in the situation again. Maybe you can respond to that? Mr. Bernanke. I think that is right. Either you have to be 100 percent confident in the private thing you set up, or alternatively, if you think there is a scenario in which the government would come in ex post, then it might be a good idea to make sure the government gets paid appropriately ex ante, and that the rules of the game are laid out in advance. Mr. Miller. But instead of the government, if you can create a facility that was independent of government, but established by government, let us say, that the profits were held, and they were not abused by Congress as a slush fund to be able to take the money from, if you just look at the profits that GSEs are making today, if there is an entity doing that of an equivalent that was backed by some guarantee for ``X'' amount of years to allow the market to recover and stability to occur, and those reserves--and the g-fee alone probably in 8 to 10 years would be $800 billion minimum if you charge a reasonable reinsurance fee on the mortgage-backed securities, that is probably $200 billion in 8 to 10 years. You have a trillion dollars, which is 6 times the risk the government took in the worst downturn we have ever seen, would that not add to market security and stability? Mr. Bernanke. The question there, I think, is whether this new entity could charge those g-fees if you had competition, and would you be allowing private-sector competition. Mr. Miller. The goal is to allow the private sector in. They are not crowding in today, and that is what we want to do. We want to get them in, but we still need to provide a surety and liquidity. That is my concern. Mr. Bernanke. That is right. Mr. Miller. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Massachusetts, Mr. Lynch. Mr. Lynch. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And welcome, Chairman Bernanke, and thank you for your service and your willingness to come before the committee and help us with our work. I want to stay right on that line of questioning that Mr. Miller actually began. As you may know, both the House and Senate are actively considering legislative proposals to reform the GSEs, and I think most of us on both sides of the aisle realize some reform is necessary. Now, I won't ask you to comment on any particular legislative proposal, I am not sure you would anyway, but you are a scholar of the Great Depression, and, as you know, Fannie Mae and the FHA are sort of creations of the New Deal, and they are--I wanted to ask you, historically the 30-year fixed mortgage, which is really a major innovation, prior to the government getting in, GSEs getting in and providing that backstop, was that available and-- Mr. Bernanke. No. Mr. Lynch. --was the private sector successful in trying to create that? Mr. Bernanke. During the Depression and that period of time, people usually took out 5-year balloon mortgages and refinanced them sequentially. Mr. Lynch. In terms of the last 80 years of government support, and that is really what has created opportunities for middle-income homeowners--well, middle-income potential homeowners from getting into the market, and as we are grappling with this GSE reform, I am very concerned about what happens to rates. I can't--I do agree with Mr. Miller, there seems to be some requirement of a backstop at some point, and obviously you want the taxpayer to be as far back as possible, and that the initial cushion or the initial loss, if necessary, would be absorbed by the private sector. And we are trying to figure out a way of preserving an affordable 30-year fixed mortgage, keep that market going, without having the taxpayer take all that risk up front. That is what we are trying to grapple with, and I am wondering if you can help us with that. Mr. Bernanke. Earlier, the chairman asked me about passing on subsidies to the consumer. I don't think that government backstops are very effective in lowering rates unless they have a price control on the interest rate that the-- Mr. Lynch. Isn't that a function of risk, though? If the private sector knows that at a certain point--like with the terrorist risk insurance that we debated here, because the industry knew there was a backstop beyond which they would not be responsible, it did, in fact, result in a lower rate. Mr. Bernanke. Right, to some extent, but a lot of it doesn't get passed through. What I was going to add, though, was that the argument for thinking about government participation is exactly the situation like we faced the last few years where there is a big housing problem, and private sector mortgage providers or securitizers are, for whatever reason, not willing to act countercyclically, then is there a role for the government to support this process? And the question we were just discussing is if that is going to happen anyway, is there a case for setting up the rules in advance in some sense and figuring out what the government ought to charge for whatever protection it is prepared to provide? Mr. Lynch. Okay. Sir, I want to thank you for your service. I have heard stories that this might be your last appearance before this committee for this purpose, and I think you have served us very well under very, very difficult circumstances-- Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Mr. Lynch. --and I appreciate your service to your country. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Royce. Mr. Royce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, I think the risk weighting at the end of the day is only as good as the metrics that we develop. I am thinking back to Basel I, and now we are looking at the final Basel III. The Basel III includes a risk weighting of 20 percent for debt issued by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and the rule includes a risk weighting of zero for unconditional debt issued by Ireland, by Portugal, by Spain, and by other OECD countries with no country risk classification. Both of these risk weightings are, in my memory, identical to the risk weightings under the original Basel I. So my concern is that we should have learned a few things about those metrics, given the consequences of the clear failure, and yet here we have the accord of 1988 looking an awful lot like this particular accord. Given what we have experienced, the failure of the GSEs, the propping up of many European economies, do you think these weightings accurately reflect the actual risk posed by these exposures? Mr. Bernanke. Basel III and all Basel agreements are international agreements. And each country can take that floor and do whatever it wants above that floor. We would not allow any U.S. bank to hold Greek debt at zero weight, I assure you. Mr. Royce. Yes. Mr. Bernanke. In terms of GSEs, GSE mortgage-backed securities have not created any loss whatsoever. They have to the taxpayer, but not to the holders of those securities. So that, I don't think, has been a problem. It is not just the risk weights, though, but Basel III also has significantly increased the amount of high-quality capital the banks have to hold for a given set of risky assets. Mr. Royce. But it still seems to me that at the end of the day, in which--with respect to what you are working out as a calculation, you have a situation where high-risk countries like Spain and Portugal, should they receive the same risk weight as exposures to the United States? And that is the way that would be handled, I think, in Europe, but it just seems that should have been addressed in the calculus. Mr. Bernanke. One way to address it is through stress testing, where you create a scenario which assumes that certain sovereign debt bears losses, and then calculate capital into those scenarios. So, that is a bit of a backstop. Mr. Royce. Let me ask you another question, which goes to this issue of the countercyclical role in the housing market that the government should play. And such a role obviously would be far better than the role government played during the last crisis, which was extraordinarily procyclical, if we look back over the greatly ballooned bubble and subsequent bust that was developed as a result of housing policy and a lot of the actions taken. Title II of the PATH Act has several provisions meant to allow FHA to play that countercyclical role. The goal obviously is to greatly expand eligibility, right, during the PATH Act-- if the PATH Act were enacted, and that would get us to the point of that borrower eligibility in such a circumstance. Would you agree enabling FHA to play an expanded role in times of crisis, as suggested under the Act, will help ensure continued access to the mortgage market for a great majority of borrowers regardless of the market conditions that we might face? Mr. Bernanke. I am not advocating a specific plan. I am just pointing out that we need to think about the situation where there is a lot of stress in the market, and then we need some kind of backstop. I obviously haven't studied this proposal, but it seems to me that FHA could be structured to provide such a backstop. It would depend on the details, but that would be one way to have the government provide a backstop. Mr. Royce. I thank you very much, Chairman Bernanke, for attending the hearing here today and for your answers. And we will probably be in consultation later with some additional questions. Mr. Bernanke. Certainly. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Green. Mr. Green. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Mr. Bernanke, for appearing again. And I trust that this will not be your last visit. I believe that our country has benefited greatly from your service, and not just the service itself, but the way you have conducted yourself in a time of great turmoil, so I am hopeful that you will be back. I would like to, for just a moment, ask you to visit with us about the issue of certainty and uncertainty, confidence, optimism, because while you may do a lot of things, if consumer confidence or producers don't have confidence, that can have a significant impact on long-term growth. Confidence is important to growth. I read through your paper, by the way, and I am very, very excited about some of the things that you have said, but I didn't get quite enough on the question of confidence. Would you please elaborate a bit? Mr. Bernanke. I think it is quite true that business confidence, homebuilder confidence, and consumer confidence are very important, and good policies promote confidence. The Fed policy, congressional policy, we want to try to create a framework where people understand what is happening, and they believe they have confidence that the basics of macroeconomic stability will be preserved. It is a difficult thing. To some extent, it is a political talent to be able to create confidence in your constituents. So nobody has a magic formula for that, but clearly the more we can demonstrate that we are working together to try to solve these important problems, the more likely we are going to instill confidence in the public, and that in turn will pay off in economic terms. Mr. Green. I compliment you, and I would like to focus on one aspect of what you said about working together. I contend that this is an important element in instilling confidence. And I believe that the American economy is quite resilient. It is strong, notwithstanding some of the weaknesses that have been exposed. The reason I know it is strong is because it has survived Congress. If the economy can survive Congress, I am confident that it will thrive eventually. But things that we do, repealing continually, or attempting to repeal some of the significant aspects of bills that have passed that will impact the American people, I am not sure how much confidence these things engender. More than 30, 40 attempts to repeal the Affordable Care Act, an attempt to repeal Dodd-Frank without replacement, an attempt to repeal the CFPB without a good sense of what the replacement will be. It seems to me that at some point we in Congress have to do more to engender the confidence that will cause the American people to want to buy, to want to invest, to want to produce. And I think that Congress has a significant role it could play, and unfortunately we have not--we have not been able to work together to the extent that the American people are confident that we will do things to help create jobs, to help build a broader economy. You have been very focused on jobs, very focused. We have not been as focused on jobs. Legislation that can produce jobs, much of it has lingered and has not had an opportunity to move forward. I just believe that in the final analysis, your good work, while it is going to be lauded and applauded, still needs some help from the policymakers in terms of working together to instill confidence. Confidence is needed. I think this economy is ready to blossom, but when I talk to business people, they say to me, we need confidence, we need to know that the rules are going to be static and not dynamic. Consumers say to me, I need confidence. I will buy a house when I am confident that the system is going to remain static and not dynamic. I thank you for your service, and I trust that we will be able to help instill the confidence to augment and supplement the good work that you have done. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Virginia, Mr. Hurt. Mr. Hurt. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here today, and we thank you for your hard work. I represent a rural district in Virginia, one that has not seen the same economic growth that other places in this country have seen. We still have places in our district where we have jobless rates at double digits. And we certainly look to Washington to adopt policies that will make it easier for our businesses to succeed, our families to succeed, as opposed to making things more difficult. In listening to your remarks, you talk about systemic-- adopting policies that go to systemic importance. Obviously Basel III, it seems to me you discussed Basel III in terms of what is systemically important. You also tip your hat to Main Street, talking about how the Fed has adopted policies to support Main Street, jobs, consumers, things that we all care about. In the aftermath of the rules that were adopted earlier this month relating to Basel III, Frank Keating with the American Bankers Association said that--asked the question, are we making things easier, or are we making things more difficult, and essentially said, if we are making them harder, that is not what we need for our economy. That is not what a recovering economy needs. So as I think about what we need in my rural southside Virginia district, I think about community banks, and I think about what an important lifeblood they are to our Main Street economy. And I wonder if you could talk a little bit about the reasoning behind not just exempting community banks from the application rule that you all have adopted, and why you did that. Mr. Bernanke. And I agree with you about the importance of community banks, particularly in rural areas which might not be served by larger institutions. It is also important, of course, for community banks to be well-capitalized so that they can continue to lend during difficult periods, they don't fail, so we want to be sure that they are well-capitalized. But in terms of the final Basel III rule that we just put out, we were very responsive to the concerns raised by community banks. They raised a number of specific issues relating, for example, to the risk weighting of mortgages, relating to the treatment of other comprehensive income, trust preferreds, a variety of things that they were concerned about, which we responded to. And that is part of our broader attempt through outreach, through meeting with advisory councils and so on to understand the needs of community banks and to make sure that we do everything we can to protect them. The-- Mr. Hurt. Have--go ahead. Mr. Bernanke. I was going to say that Basel III is primarily aimed at the largest internationally active firms, and most of the rule was just not relevant to small firms. Mr. Hurt. Clearly, you all tried to make some accommodations for community banks, and I recognize that. I guess my question is, is there a reason that you all--if you could talk a little bit about why you all concluded that you could not exempt them entirely. And I guess the second question that I have is, do you think--based on your studies or anybody else's studies--that these rules will have a disproportionate effect on community banks? Obviously, that is the heart of the concern, that the smaller banks have a much more difficult time complying with regulations than obviously the largest banks. Mr. Bernanke. Again, I don't think that Basel III is primarily aimed at community banks. And the amount of bureaucracy and rules is not significantly different from what they are doing now. In terms of capital, the community banks already typically held more capital as a ratio than larger banks do, and our calculations are that community banks are already pretty much compliant with the Basel III rules. We don't expect them to have to raise substantial amounts of new capital. Mr. Hurt. So you don't believe there will be a disproportionate effect on the smaller banks in complying with these additional regulations? Mr. Bernanke. Smaller banks are disproportionately affected by the entire collection of rules that they face, ranging from bank secrecy to a variety of consumer rules, et cetera, et cetera. I think that your constituents may not be distinguishing Basel III specifically from all the other different rules that they face. And, of course, the small bank just has fewer resources, fewer people to deal with the range of regulatory and statutory requirements that the banks have to deal with. Mr. Hurt. And just finally, in one of your earlier appearances here, we talked a little bit about the regulatory structure, what is perceived among some as a micromanagement by bank examiners and regulators in the function of the Federal Reserve as an examiner. Are you able to give us any indication of what has been done in the last 2 years or so to try to improve that? I know that you had mentioned that there were some things that the Federal Reserve had in mind and was trying to work with our smaller banks. Mr. Bernanke. Yes. I am not going to have time to go through the whole list, but we have a Community Depository Institution Advisory Council that meets with the Board, and gives us their perspective. We have a special subcommittee. Mr. Hurt. My time has expired, but do you believe that these efforts have been successful? Mr. Bernanke. I think we have made definite progress, yes. Mr. Hurt. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Cleaver. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you, Mr. Bernanke, for being here. You have had a lot of compliments today. In my business, it is called a eulogy, but that is--I am not trying to frighten you. Even the Twinkie came back. But I also want to thank you for your service. The stimulus, the Fed stimulus, has been roundly criticized by many. Can you in a short time express what you believe would be the consequences of easing quantitative easing prematurely? Mr. Bernanke. Again, it is important to talk about our overall monetary policy stance. Our intention is to keep monetary policy highly accommodative for the foreseeable future, and the reason that is necessary is because inflation is below our target, and unemployment is still quite high. In terms of asset purchases, though, I have been very clear that we are going to be responding to the data, and if the data are stronger than we expect, we will move more quickly, at the same time maintaining the accommodation-to-rate policy. If the data are less strong, if they don't meet the kinds of expectations we have about where the economy is going, then we would delay that process or even potentially increase purchases for a time. So we intend to be very responsive to incoming data both in terms of our asset purchase program, but it is also very important to understand that our overall policy, including our rate policy, is going to remain highly accommodative. Mr. Cleaver. Thank you. One of your former colleagues, Tom Hunting, from my hometown, has repeatedly warned in papers that he has written that too-big-to-fail is still a major threat to the U.S. economy. He suggests that in many instances, many of the huge financial institutions have gotten even larger. Do you think that if we went through again what we went through a few years ago, that we would be in a situation where we would almost be required to save the U.S. economy and perhaps even the world economy from a depression because those--or we would have to step in again to bail out these major corporations, AIG and-- Mr. Bernanke. I think there is more work to be done before we feel completely comfortable about systemic firms. The Dodd- Frank Act and Basel III and other international agreements provide a framework for working towards the day, which is not here yet, where we can declare too-big-to-fail a thing of the past, but we do have some tools now that we didn't have in 2008, 2009. Very importantly, we have the Orderly Liquidation Authority of the FDIC--the Federal Reserve supports the FDIC in that-- which would allow us to do a much more orderly resolution of a failing firm that would take into account the impact on financial market stability, unlike 2008, 2009, when we had no such tools and were looking for ad hoc ways to try to prevent these firms from failing. In addition, these firms are now much better capitalized than they were. And we are making other reforms that will make it much less likely that this situation will arise. But I wouldn't be saying the truth if I said the problem is gone. It is not gone. We need to keep following through on the various programs here, and I think we need to keep doing what is necessary to make sure that this problem is solved for good. Mr. Cleaver. But the question is--and I was here as we went through all of this. We didn't have the time, we were told, and actually I believe, to rationally and thoughtfully consider all the options. And my fear is that if something happened even--I agree with you. In Dodd-Frank, we tried to reduce the likelihood that this was going to happen, but what assurance do we have that we would have time for action by the Fed, by Congress? Thank you. Mr. Bernanke. We have the framework now. We have the Orderly Liquidation Authority. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Ohio, Mr. Stivers. Mr. Stivers. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And Chairman Bernanke, thank you for being here today. I really appreciate your willingness to come and answer all our questions. I am going to try to get through Basel III as well as some QE questions, and we will see how my time goes. The first thing I want to talk about is following up on the questions Mr. Hurt asked. And you--I will try to quote. You said that Basel III was not primarily aimed at community banks, and it is clear that it is aimed at the larger financial institutions which helped create the financial crisis. And I agree with you that it won't result in most community banks having to raise capital, because their capital is normally higher, but for a few community banks that don't have capital right now, where they have not as much access to the capital markets, it actually could harm them. And none of these banks are going to be too-big-to-fail; nobody is going to come in and bail them out. They also aren't so interconnected. And I am just curious why, given that Basel III is voluntarily compliant internationally, we didn't just exempt out the community banks? Mr. Bernanke. I think it is important that they be well- capitalized, both to protect the deposit insurance fund, to protect their local communities and the borrowers that depend on them. And we have seen--in the past we have seen financial crises that were small firms, like in the Depression and in the savings and loan crisis, so I think they do need to have capital. But on this issue that you mentioned, we are giving really long transitions. We aren't saying, you have to have this level of capital tomorrow. And so banks can raise capital through retained earnings and through other mechanisms as well. Mr. Stivers. Right. And I appreciate that. I don't think it is a burden on most community banks, but I do worry about a few of them, and I think it could result in consolidation in the industry and less community banks that serve some of our rural areas, and that troubles me a little bit. Mr. Bernanke. No. I agree with that concern. Mr. Stivers. The second thing I want to recognize in your Basel III is that you, I think appropriately, recognize that activity, for example, international activity, increases systemic risk, but I was a little troubled that you continue to use artificial asset numbers. I am from Ohio. We have a lot of regional banks that serve the middle market that are either based in Ohio or have a major presence in Ohio. And, you use the $10 billion number at very bottom for the smallest banks; the $50 billion up to $250 billion. And if you look at sort of the size of all the 50 largest banks in America, there is really--there are kind of some tiers. There are the top banks above $2 trillion, and there are 3 of those, I think--I'm sorry--2 of those--there are 2 more above $1 trillion, between $1 trillion and $2 trillion, and then there are 3 more above half a trillion dollars, but then it falls way off to 350. And you set that top limit for regional banks at 250. And there are banks that are regional banks that are essentially super community banks that are above that 250 to 350. A couple of them have a major presence in Ohio and serve our middle market. And I guess I would ask where you picked that artificial number of 250, because most people would recognize both PNC and U.S. Bank as regional banks. Mr. Bernanke. We have met with middle-market banks and tried to understand their concerns. The basic philosophy here is that both the capital requirements and the supervisory requirements are gradated with size. So, for example, the largest banks will have capital surcharges. Where we have failed to gradate appropriately, of course, we can go back and try to figure out how to get it right. Mr. Stivers. I appreciate that. And I would really urge you to take a look at the major cliffs in our asset sizes, because they really do--that spell themselves out. And I think the big jump between, say--there are no banks between $350 million and $500 million. There are 2 at just above $350 million, and then there is nobody until you get to almost $550 million. So, that is a big jump, and I think--I would urge you to take a look at that. And the last question I would like to quickly ask is about--you talked about stress testing a lot for the banks. And in your QE and the way you judge QE portfolio, would you be willing to submit the Federal Reserve's QE to the same kind of stress testing under the same kind of provisions you provide for these banks of potential interest rate spikes and inflation? Mr. Bernanke. The stress test has a different purpose for the Fed, which is to effect how much remittances we send to the Treasury. And we have done various stress tests in that respect, and many of them are publicly available. We have a number of research papers. And there are also outside researchers, the IMF and others, who have done these tests. And the bottom line is that for any reasonable interest rate path, this is going to end up being a profitable policy for the taxpayer. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Peters. Mr. Peters. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, Chairman Bernanke, thank you for being here today and for your service. Last week, the Bank of Japan announced that they were going to maintain their current monetary policy, which, as you know, includes significant devaluation of the yen for the purposes of improving the competitiveness of Japanese exports. The yen has fallen in value almost 30 percent compared to the dollar since last year. And Japan, as you also know, is joining the U.S.-led Trans-Pacific Partnership trade talks. I have raised a number of concerns about Japan's entry into the trade talks until they open their markets, particularly to U.S. autos. And while they continue to manipulate their currency, this increases my concerns, and it could make our trade deficit even worse. I know in 2011 you expressed concern with China's devaluation of their currency. I am quoting you saying, ``Right now our concern is that the Chinese currency policy is blocking what might be a more normal recovery process in the global economy, and it is to an extent hurting our recovery.'' Could you please discuss your views on Japan's currency policy, its impact on the economy, and do you believe that their currency policy is hurting the economic recovery in the globe right now? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. There are some fundamental differences between China's policy and Japan's policy. China has managed its exchange rate and kept it for many years below its equilibrium level in order to increase its exports. That is what economists call a zero sum game: What they gain we lose, basically. The Japanese approach is different. They are not manipulating their exchange rate. They are not directly trying to set their exchange right at a given level. What they are doing is engaging in strong domestic monetary policy measures, trying to break the deflation that they have had for about 15 years, and a side effect of that is that the yen has weakened. The G20 and the G7 have discussed these matters, and the international consensus is that as long as a country is using domestic policy tools for domestic purposes, that would be an acceptable approach. Now, I recognize that movements in exchange rates do affect competition. You said you are from Michigan, right? Yes. So I can see where your concern would come from. I think that it is in our interest, though, to see Japan strengthened, to see their economy grow faster. It will increase our market there as well as the competitive supply. And over time, if they do, in fact, achieve positive inflation, that increase in prices there will partially offset the exchange rate movement. So, I recognize the concern. I don't know how big an effect it has had so far. I have actually talked to a couple of people in the auto industry at some of the companies to try and get their sense. But, again, there is a difference, which is that Japan is trying to expand its overall economy, and therefore, there is a benefit as well as a cost, and that benefit is a stronger Japanese economy and a stronger Asian market. Mr. Peters. To pick up from that point, so if you could kind of give me some sense, as you wind down your quantitative easing activities while Japan maintains this current policy which is driving down the yen, do you believe it is going to have an impact on American manufacturing and exports as you wind down as they continue that policy? Mr. Bernanke. It could. It could to some extent, but, of course, as you know, for example, many Japanese producers produce in the United States, and there is a sense that for a number of reasons, including productivity and others, that U.S. manufacturing is actually generally becoming more competitive globally than it has been in some time. So I don't think that this change in the value of the yen would offset that underlying trend. Mr. Peters. If I could just switch briefly, this is another big topic, but if you could touch on it. There have been some recent reports, in fact, a recent IMF report came out to talk about monetary policy and its impact on inequality in the United States. As you know, inequality has expanded dramatically, particularly in the last 20, 30 years. And in the report they talk about monetary policies having a much more significant role in driving historical inequality patterns in the United States than has been expected in--or that has been anticipated and certainly written about in the economic literature. Would you comment briefly? Do you believe that monetary policy has a significant impact on inequality as we are seeing it and-- Mr. Bernanke. No, I don't think so. The purpose of monetary policy is, first of all, to keep inflation low, and everybody is affected by inflation, and to maintain employment at the highest level that the economy can sustain. And, of course, jobs are critical to the welfare of the broad middle class of Americans. So I really don't understand that. It is true that in the short run, some of the tools that we have involve changing asset prices, so higher stock prices and things of that sort, but we can't affect those things in the long run. It is only a short-run transmission mechanism that is involved there. Mr. Peters. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Tennessee, Mr. Fincher. Mr. Fincher. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, Chairman Bernanke, thank you for your service and for being here today. I am going to read a paragraph, for my benefit probably more than yours, to get started, and then I have a couple of questions. ``The Federal Reserve was intended to be a fully independent central bank and monetary authority. The authors of the original Federal Reserve Act did not want to subject the institution to the whims of politicians, but, rather, set clear objectives for the institution in the interests of fostering the macroeconomic stability. That independence has eroded significantly since the 2008 financial crisis, when the Federal Reserve and the Treasury Department initially took coordinated steps to stabilize the economy. One persistent concern--that is, if the central bank's independence is infringed upon by the government, fiscal authorities can compel the Fed to monetize sovereign debt.'' A couple of questions. With what has happened with quantitative easing, I was looking at the Dow a few minutes ago, 15,400; Nasdaq, 3,604; and 1,680 for the S&P. To Chairman Hensarling's comments earlier, I think the private sector is addicted to the government money. And anytime you talk about cutting the money off, there is a panic. Because we have our own currency and we can manipulate that currency, unemployment where it is, inflation where it is, with the entitlements in this country where they are--I am saying a lot here, but will we ever get to back to that place of unemployment at 5 percent? I live in a part of the country, in a rural part of the country with a lot of farmers, a lot of agricultural real estate. We have seen land prices go through the roof, and one reason I think we have is interest rates are so low that people can borrow money. It is just--it is there. But that causes problems, also, because if this thing ever does turn around, how do you stop it? And interest rates are how you stop it. But the country also is in debt up to their eyeballs, which creates another problem. High interest rates breaks the back of the country. So I said a lot, but are you concerned that pumping the money into the economy, when we stop that, can the country take it? Can the private sector react? And how do we do that? Mr. Bernanke. The reason for the low interest rates is because the economy is weak and inflation is low. And even if the Fed wasn't engaging in asset purchases, interest rates would still be quite low, as they are in other countries, for example. One reason that asset markets react to what the Fed says is that they are trying to determine whether the Fed will provide sufficient support for the economy to get back to full employment. That is our job, that is our mandate, when the economy is away from full employment, to try to provide the financial support that will move the economy in that direction. Mr. Fincher. Do you not think the politics over the past 4, 5, 6 years are playing more of a role than they did 6, 7 years ago? Mr. Bernanke. No, I don't. Your earlier point about collaborating with the Treasury in the financial crisis, that had nothing to do with monetary policy. That had to do with the two main financial institutions in the government working together to prevent a big financial collapse. And I think the collaboration was needed there. But at no time during the crisis or at any point did the Administration, the Congress, or the Treasury Department ever tell the Fed, we need monetary policy of ``X.'' We have always maintained that independence, and we think it is critically important that we maintain it. Mr. Fincher. I just have about a minute left. I fear that the government's intervention into trying to make sure the private sector is running at full capacity creates all sorts of problems. Now that I am up here and I see how big this is--I had a constituent the other day who brought this point up, and he said, with the regulatory policies that we have, with the choking effect that some say, the big government is really good for big business, the unintended consequences, because the big businesses can react to big government. The smaller businesses have a harder time doing that with the resources they have. And I thought about it a minute, and it is a great point. Again, I am fearful that we are out of control, pumping the money in. The private sector is addicted to the pumping of the money. And when we ever shut that off, there is going to be a reaction. The reaction now that the stock market is 15,000, if we drop back to 12,000, again you are going to see a panic. What do we do then? So many people, Chairman Bernanke, think now that the government's role is to step in and save the day. And this is taxpayer money. This is very, very dangerous. Mr. Bernanke. There is sort of an idea going around that the Fed can step away and not do anything. We have to do something. We have to have interest rates somewhere. The Fed does control our money supply. So we have to do something, and I think that we are better off trying to get the economy moving than not. Mr. Fincher. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlemen has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Foster. Mr. Foster. Thank you. Chairman Bernanke, I think when it is time for the T-shirts to be passed out at your retirement party, a very good candidate for that would be the $34 trillion swing in household net worth. When we have seen in the last several years the $16 trillion drop in household net worth caused by a complete failure of the Republican fiscal, regulatory, and monetary policy replaced by an $18 trillion recovery, it is one of the most impressive achievements. And there is no doubt that, of the three legs of financial policy--monetary, fiscal, and regulatory--monetary policy deserves a lot of credit. So I just--you deserve the compliments you have been getting. The question I would like to pursue is, it is my understanding that the Fed and the CBO maintain roughly comparable macroeconomic models. And in the last few weeks, the CBO has analyzed two different macroeconomic scenarios: one in which Congress has passed the Senate proposal for comprehensive immigration reform and a path to citizenship, which they found resulted in about a $1.5 trillion increase in economic activity over the next 10 years and about a $200 billion reduction in the Federal debt; and the second scenario, in which the Republicans succeed in blocking comprehensive immigration reform, resulting in a $200 billion larger level of Federal debt and a $1.5 trillion decrease in economic activity compared to the other scenario. And so my question is, do you anticipate, given this policy uncertainty, that you are going to have to separately consider both of those scenarios, both the high-debt, low-growth scenario caused by Republican obstruction and the high-growth, low-debt scenario that would follow congressional passage of the Senate comprehensive immigration reform bill? Mr. Bernanke. To begin with, we haven't done any comparable analysis of the economic implications of immigration. I think, in general, a growing population, more talented people, all those things do help the economy grow. A younger population will also help us deal with our aging situation. To use a cliche, we are a Nation of immigrants. All that being said, there are a lot of details in setting up a program in terms of how it should be monitored and managed and so on that I really think are the province of Congress. And I don't really want to try to set immigration policy. I really think that the details there have to be worked out in Congress. Mr. Foster. I guess my question is, how do you deal with, when there are policy choices being made by Congress with fairly large macroeconomic effects, this in your forward planning? Mr. Bernanke. Generally, we take those decisions as given, and we try to figure out what the best thing we can do is given the economic environment we find ourselves in. So, with respect to fiscal policy and the restraint this year from fiscal policy, we sort of take that as given, again, and try to figure out how much monetary accommodation is therefore needed. And, with respect to immigration, I think these are much longer-term propositions; these are gains and losses over many years. And the Fed, because it focuses mostly on short-term cyclical movements in the economy, our focus is typically not 10 or 20 years but, rather, the next few years. Mr. Foster. Okay. I would like to follow up on Representative Royce's questions about the countercyclical element in Federal housing policies, which are present, as he pointed out, not only in the Republican PATH Act proposal but also in the Democratic principles for housing market reform. There was also a recent front-page article in The Wall Street Journal that was entitled, ``Central Bankers Hone Tools to Pop Bubbles.'' Had you seen that? Mr. Bernanke. ``Central Bankers-- Mr. Foster. ``Hone Tools to Pop Bubbles.'' It discussed the efforts in various countries to implement countercyclical housing policies. Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Foster. So you have seen that. The American Enterprise Institute is also hosting a 2-day workshop on this subject at the end of this month. So my question is, do you believe that regulators have today the tools necessary, as well as the collective will, to address the development of potential asset bubbles, such as the housing bubble from which we are still recovering? Mr. Bernanke. We have some tools. For example, Basel III included a countercyclical capital requirement. In other words, if we see the economy growing too fast with too much credit being extended, we could raise capital requirements. I think it makes a big difference that the CFPB and other agencies have done a lot to eliminate the worst kinds of mortgage abuses that were very important in the housing boom. The Federal Reserve has recently issued some guidance to banks on leveraged lending and other kinds of practices that could contribute to asset bubbles. All that being said, we want to make the financial system as fair and transparent as possible, but I don't think we can guarantee that we can prevent any bubble. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Indiana, Mr. Stutzman. Mr. Stutzman. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here today. And I really want to thank you for your comments earlier about what Congress should be focused on, and that is the long- term liabilities to our country. I do believe that if we would address those issues, the trajectory of our economy would change, instead of being focused on such a near-term rhetoric and the effects to the economy by short-term policies. So I appreciate what you mentioned earlier. I want to talk a little bit about employment. For the entire U.S. workforce, employers have added far more part-time employees in 2013, averaging 93,000 a month, seasonally adjusted, than full-time workers, which have averaged 22,000. Last year, the reverse was true, with employers adding 31,000 part-time workers monthly compared with 171,000 full-time ones. Earlier in June, I, along with other colleagues from Indiana, wrote HHS Secretary Kathleen Sebelius and Treasury Secretary Jack Lew to find out whether or not they had forecasted the impact of the Affordable Care Act on part-time workers who are currently just above the 30-hour threshold. Does this shift of a lot of workers, many workers, from the full-time category to part-time status at all affect your statutory mandate to reach full employment? Mr. Bernanke. I think it does. As I mentioned in my testimony, there are a number of problems with the labor market. Unemployment is one problem, but long-term unemployment and underemployment--and by ``underemployment,'' I mean people who are either working fewer hours than they would like or possibly are working at jobs well below their skill level--are also indicative of a weak labor market. And a stronger economy will help, I think, in all those dimensions. So, yes, that is part of our concern. And as we look at the unemployment rate and try to determine what it means for the labor market, we look at these other indicators as well. Mr. Stutzman. You mentioned earlier that the taxes at the beginning of the year were affecting the economy. You mentioned something else, that I can't recall. Mr. Bernanke. There were spending cuts from before, and then there were tax increases and then sequestration. Mr. Stutzman. That is right, sequestration and the tax increases. Do you believe that the Affordable Care Act is dragging the economy or slowing the economy down at all with the transition that we are currently going through and the effort of implementation? Mr. Bernanke. It is very hard to make any judgment. One thing that we hear in the commentary we get at the FOMC is that some employers are hiring part-time in order to avoid the mandate there. So, we have heard that. But, on the other hand, a couple of observations: one, the very high level of part-time employment has been around since the beginning of the recovery, and we don't fully understand it; two, those data come from the household survey, and they are a little bit inconsistent with some of the data from the firm survey, which suggests that work weeks haven't really declined very much. So I would say at this point that we are withholding judgment on that question. Mr. Stutzman. Do you think that a delay in the mandates would be appropriate? Mr. Bernanke. That is beyond my pay grade. It would depend on questions of how much time is needed to fully implement the bill. Mr. Stutzman. Okay. Thank you. With about a minute left, I would like to touch on some of the global economic concerns and other countries beginning a trend of currency devaluation in fear of currency wars that might follow. Could you comment on that at all? Mr. Bernanke. As I mentioned in an earlier answer, the international community makes a distinction between attempts to manipulate an individual exchange rate in order to gain an unfair advantage in export markets versus using monetary or fiscal policy to achieve domestic objectives that may have the side effect of weakening the currency. So this was the example with Japan. Japan has taken policy actions that have weakened the yen, but that wasn't the focus of those actions. Their actions were intended to break the deflation which they faced for the last 15 years or so to get their economy growing more quickly and to get back to a 2 percent or so inflation objective. If they are successful, there may be some exchange rate effects, as the earlier question raised, but there also will be the benefit that a stronger Japanese economy and a stronger Asian economy will increase world growth and be a benefit to the United States, as well. So those are the distinctions between those different types of management of the currency. Mr. Stutzman. Okay. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Murphy. Mr. Murphy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, as well. I want to echo what has been said already in thanking you for your service to our country. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Mr. Murphy. There has been a lot of talk already in the committee about the talk of tapering in the last several weeks. And the Board of Governors has come out and tried to clarify some of those comments. It has been turmoil somewhat on Wall Street, these ups and downs. And this isn't a knock on Wall Street, but my concern is really Main Street. What we have seen in the last--I guess since May--is a 40 percent increase in interest rates on mortgage rates. What do you think we should be doing? What can you do? And what do you think is the effect of this pretty sudden and sharp rise in interest rates? Mr. Bernanke. First of all, we are going to continue to communicate our policy intentions and to make clear that, notwithstanding how the mix of policy tools change, we intend to maintain a highly accommodative monetary policy for the foreseeable future. I think that message is beginning to get through, and I think that will be helpful. More generally, we will be watching to see if the movement in mortgage rates has any material effect on housing. The main thing is to see housing continue to grow, more jobs in construction and the like. And as we have said, if we think that mortgage rate increases are threatening that progress, then we would have to take additional action in the monetary sphere to try to address that. Of course, there is always hope for Congress to look at problems that remain in the housing market in terms of people underwater, in terms of refinancing of underwater mortgages, and other kinds of issues that Congress could examine. But we are going to be looking at it from the perspective of whether or not the housing recovery is continuing to a degree sufficient to provide the necessary support for the overall economic recovery. Mr. Murphy. Thank you. My background is as a CPA. I worked at Deloitte for a while, dealing with Sarbanes-Oxley, and as an auditor. So I am not one to say we need more or less regulation, necessarily, but that we need smarter regulation. And, certainly, being here now, trying to understand all the different regulators, and dealing with a lot of the institutions in my district, especially the small and medium- sized banks, what are you doing to work with all the different regulators to try to streamline and make it easier for these small institutions? Mr. Bernanke. One of the vehicles that we have is an organization called the FFIEC, which is basically the place where the banking regulators gather and talk to each other about policy and regulatory decisions. And the FFIEC has a regular committee which is focused on small community banks and trying to find ways to reduce the burden of regulation and to find ways to make it easier for them to deal with the regulations that do bear on smaller banks. As far as the Fed itself is concerned, I mentioned earlier that we have an advisory council of community institutions, we have a special subcommittee that looks at the effects of our regulations on smaller institutions. We have had meetings around the country, outreach, special training sessions for examiners and the like. So we do take that very seriously, recognizing that there is a heavy regulatory burden on community banks, and we want to do everything we can to mitigate that. And I would just perhaps add that Congress probably has a role here, too, since some of the things that community banks have to deal with come from the statute and not the regulation. Mr. Murphy. Thank you. I agree with that. So this kind of leads to my next question about the systemic importance of banks and determining if the balance sheet is the best place we should be drawing this line. And if not, do you have any other thoughts on that? And what would the difference be in a bank with $55 billion versus say $45 billion, as far as systemic risk to our economy? Mr. Bernanke. As I have mentioned, Dodd-Frank tells us to do this in a graduated way, to have capital requirements and supervisory requirements become tougher as the size and complexity and systemic importance of the bank increases. And so there are obviously going to be certain dividing lines to try to separate banks into these different categories. But even within the categories, we are trying to distinguish between the smaller banks in that category and the larger banks in that category. And as I said earlier to a questioner on the other side of the aisle, to the extent that the rules don't provide sufficient smoothness in how they vary by type of bank, we have plenty of capacity to go back and look at them. But the basic idea is that the very largest internationally active banks should bear the hardest burden of regulation. Mr. Murphy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from South Carolina, Mr. Mulvaney. Mr. Mulvaney. Thank you. Chairman Bernanke, I want to begin by going back to some of the questions that Chairman Hensarling began with at the very outset of the hearing regarding whether or not the markets were addicted to easy money. And I have a graph that I think you have in front of you, that we would like to put up on the screen. It simply shows the correlation between the size of your balance sheet and the performance of the S&P over the course of the last 4 or 5 years. And as you can see, there is a strong argument that the two things tend to move together. So my question to you is fairly simple: What can you say to convince us and to convince the markets that you will be able to return the balance sheet to its normal size, as I think your internal study says you want to do by 2018, 2019, Mrs. Yellen says by 2025? Will you be able to do that without dragging the markets down at the same time, especially in light of what happened last month after your comments in the JEC? Mr. Bernanke. The main thing that supports the stock market or other markets is the underlying economy. I don't know what it means to say that markets are addicted. I don't think that is really a technical term in finance. But the reason, I think, that markets have improved so much since 2009 is because Fed policy and other policies have succeeded in providing a stronger economy with low inflation. Mr. Mulvaney. If the economy is growing at such a strong rate as to support some fairly dramatic increases in the stock markets that we have seen, then why are you continuing your easy-money policies? Mr. Bernanke. Profits are actually ahead of jobs. That is one of the problems. So we continue to provide easy money in order to get the job situation back to where we need it and also because inflation is below our target. I think the kind of scenario you are worried about would be most likely to happen if the Fed withdrew easy monetary policies prematurely and the economy relapsed into weakness. Then, I think you would see asset prices come down. Mr. Mulvaney. Are you satisfied that if you were called upon at some point in the future--and I am not trying to rattle any markets--to begin bringing the balance sheet back to normal size, and the markets reacted with fairly substantial reductions, you will have the staying power to keep that exit strategy despite the fact the markets are going down? Mr. Bernanke. I think the key is making sure that the markets, first of all, understand our plan, but, secondly, that we have done enough that the economy is growing on its own. If the economy is growing on its own, it won't need the Fed's help and support. And then the markets, I think, will be just fine. Mr. Mulvaney. Thank you, sir. I want to talk about something else that is a little off the beaten track. You and I have talked about it before; you mentioned it when you were here earlier this year. I am talking about remittances to the Fed. Mrs. Yellen mentioned it in a speech she gave at about the same time. And I think your written testimony at the time said they could be quite low for a time in some scenarios, particularly if interest rates were to rise quickly. Mrs. Yellen was a little stronger when she spoke to the NABE and said remittances could cease entirely for some period. You have an internal study conducted by Mr. Carpenter and others in January of this year which indicates that having the Fed generate combined earnings insufficient to cover its operating costs, dividends, and paid-in capital isn't that much of a problem, as the Fed can simply carry it on your balance sheet as a deferred asset. But it goes on to say that whenever you have done that in the past, when the Fed has done that in the past, it has been for a very short period of time and that we have never seen a period where the Fed is not able to make these remittances over a fairly long period of time. Given the fact that you have an extraordinarily large balance sheet, we have gone through this, what I think you called unprecedented expansion of the balance sheet, and given the fact that you stand to lose a tremendous amount of money in a higher-interest-rate environment--I think we had a witness here testify that a 100-basis-point interest-rate rise in a short period of time could generate losses to the Fed of in excess of hundreds of billions of dollars. If we end up in an environment where remittances from the Fed go on for an extended period of time, how would that impact the Fed's operation and especially its independence? Mr. Bernanke. It won't affect our ability to do monetary policy. Independence is up to Congress. In terms of the fiscal impact, we have done many simulations. There may be a period of regular remittances, but we have already had a period of very high remittances, almost $300 billion in the last 4 years. Mr. Mulvaney. Which you have already remitted, though. Where does the money come from? If your combined earnings don't generate enough to cover your operating expenses, your paid-in capital, and whatever else you need to pay for, where does the money come from to operate the Federal Reserve? Mr. Bernanke. From the balance sheet. We have all the resources we need to do that. Mr. Mulvaney. But if you have tremendous losses on your balance sheet because of higher interest rates, you are paying a lot higher interest to the banks that keep their excess reserves and you are negative cash, where does the money come from? Mr. Bernanke. It comes from the income from our assets. It is just that, from an accounting perspective, we don't have to recognize those losses unless we sell them. Mr. Mulvaney. Is there ever a circumstance where you go to your shareholders for a capital call? Mr. Bernanke. No. Mr. Mulvaney. And I guess that is the end of my time. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. It is the end of the gentleman's time, although I wish we could carry it out a little further. The gentlemen from Maryland, Mr. Delaney, is now recognized. Mr. Delaney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for your incomparable service to our country over the last several years of your tenure. My first question--I have several questions; I will try to ask them quickly, and I think they have relatively short answers--is, there has obviously been recent volatility in the bond markets, an uptick in rates over the last several months based on a variety of factors, and it seems to me that the economy has actually handled that pretty well. Would you agree with that assessment? Mr. Bernanke. I think it is a little early to say so far. But as I said in my remarks, I think we need to monitor particularly the housing market to see if there is any impact from higher mortgage rates. Mr. Delaney. You get a lot of very current micro data. Have you seen any data to suggest that this uptick in rates has had a negative effect on what appears to be a reasonably good housing recovery? I know, again, I understand, it is very early. Mr. Bernanke. No, I haven't seen anything that points strongly to any particular problem, but again, it is very early. Mr. Delaney. Is there any kind of second-half economic data coming out that would lead you to conclude that your original views about the economy for the second half of the year, particularly as it relates to your ability to begin to taper, has changed your views? Mr. Bernanke. I am sorry, is there any information-- Mr. Delaney. Is there any new kind of second-half economic data which causes you to think differently about the economy from what you did a month ago? Mr. Bernanke. No. Our general, broad outline is that we expect the economy to pick up probably later this year. The exact timing depends on the impact of the fiscal restraint. We should see continued improvement in the labor market, unemployment continuing to fall, and inflation moving back up toward 2 percent. That general scenario still seems to be correct. But it has not yet, obviously, been confirmed by the data. That is what we need to see. Mr. Delaney. And this notion of a highly accommodative monetary policy, I assume you can taper in the context of that position, that doesn't imply that you can't begin to taper your purchases. Mr. Bernanke. As I described in my testimony, we think of the two tools we have as having different roles. So the purpose of the asset purchases was to achieve more near-term momentum, to achieve a substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market. We are making progress on that objective. But the traditional, most reliable, most powerful tool that the Fed has is short-term interest rates. And using low short- term interest rates and guidance about those rates is going to provide us, ultimately, with sufficient monetary policy accommodation to achieve what we are trying to get to. Mr. Delaney. That sounds like you are maintaining the posture you think is important for the economy using short-term interest rates. In that context, you should have the flexibility to potentially taper consistent with what you had wanted to do. Mr. Bernanke. If the economy does more or less what I described. But as I also emphasized, that is contingent. And if the economy is stronger, we can moderate faster. If it is weaker, we can moderate more slowly. Mr. Delaney. And you don't have any data that the economy has softened or housing has softened based on this interest- rate volatility that we have seen? Mr. Bernanke. It is just really too early. We have had some strong data in some areas. This morning, we had a housing report that was a little bit weaker. But again, I think given the amount of noise in every piece of data, I don't think it is appropriate to take too strong a signal from that. Mr. Delaney. Switching gears a little bit to banks and their portfolios, which is obviously part of the responsibility of the Federal Reserve, how concerned are you about interest- rate risk that may be accumulating on the balance sheets of the regulated financial institutions based on the interest-rate environment we have been in and some of the asset shortages, if you will, or--it has been hard for banks to originate assets. How concerned are you that they are building up reasonably significant interest-rate risks in their business? Mr. Bernanke. We have been looking at that as regulators, and we are reasonably comfortable that banks are managing their interest-rate risk appropriately. Note that from the banks' perspective, even as higher interest rates reduce the value of some of their securities that they hold, higher interest rates also potentially improve their net interest margins and their profitability. So as interest rates have gone up, we have actually seen some bank stocks go up, rather than down. Mr. Delaney. Great. Thank you again for your service. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Illinois, Mr. Hultgren. Mr. Hultgren. Thank you, Chairman Hensarling. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke. I very much appreciate your time today. If I may, I would like to highlight a Crain's article from earlier this year that discussed the rash of bank closings and consolidations in and around Chicago. Certainly, there are many causes, but the article uses Hyde Park Bank, which is from President Obama's home neighborhood, to discuss one contributing cause. They talk about how the near-zero interest rates, which were set by the Fed, make it nearly impossible for banks to invest safely and earn a decent yield. I wonder, for communities banks that rely on net interest margin, how do you justify the Fed policy? And is the Fed using the tool to help one section of the economy while hurting another? Mr. Bernanke. First, I think that is not accurate. Net interest margins have come down a little but not all that much. And profitability in banks in the last few years has been generally quite good. Moreover, low interest rates, what is the purpose of low interest rates? The purpose is to give us a stronger economy. And a stronger economy means better asset quality, it means more lending opportunities. So what low interest rates take away they give on the other hand by giving a better economic environment for banks to operate in. Mr. Hultgren. Theoretically, maybe that is true. I just don't hear that from my community banks. They are struggling, partially under the regulation I think, the regulatory burden that they are feeling, but also feeling because of an interest- rate crunch, is really how they are expressing it to me. Let me switch gears. Quickly, you have been outspoken on the negative effects of Section 716 of Dodd-Frank, the swap push-out/spin-off provision. As some of my colleagues on the committee have reversed their position from last year, I wonder if you could quickly restate why Section 716 could have a negative effect on end users and systemic soundness. Mr. Bernanke. It creates additional costs, essentially, because it moves out certain kinds of instruments from the banks, makes it more difficult for banks to offer a range of services to their customers, and puts U.S. banks at a potential cost disadvantage to international competitors. Mr. Hultgren. So you would still be supportive of changing this provision in Section 716? Mr. Bernanke. We have some concerns with that provision. Of course, everything depends on what the alternative is and how the Congress makes those changes. Mr. Hultgren. Let me switch again to something else. Mr. Chairman, as you know, Dodd-Frank requires the Fed to adopt procedures to implement the new limitations on the Section 13.3 authority, its 13.3 authority. It is now 3 years later, and the Fed still has not done so. How do you justify the Fed's 3-year delay in implementing these basic restrictions on the Fed's authority to bail out nonbank firms? Mr. Bernanke. First of all, I think that the law is very clear about what we can and cannot do. And I don't think that the absence of a formal rule would allow us to do something which the law prohibits. And I mentioned earlier that the law prohibits us from bailing out individual firms using 13.3, and there would be no way we could do that. We have made a lot of progress on that rule, and I anticipate we will have that out relatively soon. Mr. Hultgren. You think by the end of the year? Mr. Bernanke. I will check with staff, but I would hope so. Mr. Hultgren. Okay. That would be great. Kind of following up on that, as well, I know there were some questions asked last time you were here--again, we always appreciate your willingness to come here and spend time with us. But I do know, hearing from some colleagues and from myself that some questions were submitted and we hadn't heard back from that. I know it has been about 4 months since you were here last time. So I am just asking again if maybe you could check on that, as well as letting us know from your staff when this final rulemaking would be done. Mr. Bernanke. We will do that. Mr. Hultgren. One last thing that I will touch on--you know what? Actually, with 1 minute left, I am going to yield back, if Chairman Hensarling has any further questions. You are okay? Okay. Then, I am going to ask one more question, if I could. And getting back to banking rules as applied to insurance companies, it seems that the adoption of GAAP accounting for mutual insurance companies remains one of the Federal Reserve's top priorities. However, statutory accounting is considered superior to GAAP for purposes of ensuring the sound and prudential regulation of insurance companies. Wouldn't applying SAP be a more prudent approach as the Fed develops capital rules for savings and loan holding companies that are predominantly in the business of insurance? Mr. Bernanke. We have a lot of issues still. We deferred the Basel rule for insurance, for savings and loan holding companies that have more than 25 percent insurance activity. So we are looking at a range of issues about how we can adapt the consolidated supervisory rules and the capital rules for insurance. And we recognize that there are some differences that we need to look at. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. Mr. Hultgren. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Ohio, Ms. Beatty. Mrs. Beatty. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Madam Ranking Member. Chairman Bernanke, I certainly join my colleagues in thanking you for all the work that you have done. We started the questions today with a series of quotes or statements from you, so I would like to end it with one and thank you for it. And that is, ``Our mission as set forth by the Congress is a critical one: to preserve price stability; to foster maximum sustainable growth in output and employment; and to promote a stable and efficient financial system that serves all Americans well and fairly.'' My question will be centered around that last part of it, the efficient financial system that will serve ``all Americans.'' I know you have had a lot of questions related to the housing market. I want to thank you for opening your testimony and starting with housing, because I am a long-term housing advocate. And in reviewing your document this morning, the multiple pages on housing put in mind this question for you. Will you speak to what impact maintaining an adequate supply of affordable housing options for first-time homeowners, as well as moderate-income buyers, has? And then, conversely, what will happen to the economy if we only promote a housing finance system where only the well-off who have the high credit scores, who have the double-digit dollars to put down, 10, 20 percent, what happens to our market there? Because when you look at what I believe is more than $10 trillion in economic value, the United States housing market certainly is inextricably linked to the performance of our Nation's economy. Mr. Bernanke. In this recovery, one of the credit areas which is not normalized is mortgage credit. And we have noted that people with lower credit scores and first-time home buyers are not able to get mortgage credit in many cases. And, of course, that is a problem for them, it is a problem for their communities, and it is a problem for the overall economy since we are looking for a stronger housing market as one of the engines to help the economy recover. So there are many reasons why mortgage credit is still tight for those borrowers, but it is definitely a concern and something we are paying close attention to. Mrs. Beatty. And let me take this a step further, because so often--and, certainly, that is the answer we get. And I think America expects this Congress to advocate for those folks. Because as soon as you say ``low-income'' and ``moderate-income,'' then someone has to stand up for them. But let's look at the flip side of this. In your opinion, let's look at what it does to the market for credit unions and banks. Because housing is not only being able to purchase the house, but it deals with construction and jobs and employment. So what responsibility do you think those credit unions and banks have to play in this environment that we are in now? Mr. Bernanke. We encourage banks to lend to credit-worthy borrowers. We certainly enforce fair-lending laws. It is important that first-time home buyers be able to get credit in order to buy a home. It is important for our economy. There are some issues still out there, as I mentioned, and I think regulators have to take responsibility for the fact that not all the rules for making mortgage loans are finished and out there. We need more clarity on those things. There is still a lot of concern among banks about so-called ``put-back risk,'' the notion that the GSEs will put back any mortgage that goes bad if there is anything, any technical flaw wrong with it. That makes the banks less likely to lend. So there are a lot of things to work on to get the mortgage market in better shape. And we are approaching this both from the monetary policy point of view, which is trying to keep mortgage rates low so that housing is of affordable, but also as regulators and working with other regulators to try to solve some of the problems that still exist in extending mortgage credit. Mrs. Beatty. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The gentlelady yields back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Florida, Mr. Ross. Mr. Ross. Thank you, Chairman Hensarling. Chairman Bernanke, I wish to begin by addressing one of your earlier comments in your opening statement, when you said that the debate concerning other fiscal policy issues, such as the status of the debt ceiling, will evolve in a way that could hamper the recovery. My concern with that is, I believe that at $17 trillion and counting in debt, as we see on our national debt clock up there, when 6 percent of our Federal budget is used to pay interest payments alone on national debt, I firmly believe that our sovereign debt should not go unpaid, but there is a tremendous difference between borrowing money to pay for an IRS ``Star Trek'' video and paying our sovereign debt. You see, I believe that it is disingenuous to say that the debate on the debt ceiling or the debt limit for this country will adversely impact us, when, in fact, 2 years ago, the credit-rating agencies came to us and said that if we don't have in place a systemic, long-term path to reduce and address our debt, that we are going to be downgraded in our ratings. It wasn't so much the debate on the debt that we had; it was the fact that we failed to take action to reduce in a systemic fashion, in a long-term fashion, our debt. Out of the debt-ceiling debates that we have had in the past, we have come out with things such as Pay-As-You-Go, the Gramm-Rudman Act. There have been good things to help us with that. So I think it is important that we acknowledge that having a healthy debate on the debt ceiling is prudent and responsible. With that, I also want to address the second part of your opening statement, when you addressed the important nonbank financial institutions, specifically the implementation of the Collins amendment. My concern with that--and going back to last week when Fed Governor Tarullo testified before the Senate Banking Committee, he told Senator Johnson that, in regard to postponing and delaying the rules, as you have testified before, on Basel III, on nonbank financial institutions--however, he said, ``That is to say that the Collins amendment does require that generally applicable capital requirements be applied to all of the holding companies we supervise.'' I look at the Collins amendment, and what concerns me is that I am afraid your hands may be tied, in that we have two different types of financial institutions here. We have the short-term funding and the banks, and we have the long-term-- and insurance companies, and yet we are going to give risk- based capital requirements, expanded requirements, based on generally accepted accounting principles, which don't apply to insurance companies, we are going to increase the cost of insurance. And I come from Florida, a State where insurance is very important. And, more importantly, this is probably going to result in a conflict between the McCarran-Ferguson Act and the implementation of a Basel III capital requirement for insurance companies. How do you feel that we can resolve that? Can we resolve that? Mr. Bernanke. So, quickly, on the debt limit, I wasn't trying to make a policy recommendation other than to say that, the last time around, we did get a pretty big shock to consumer sentiment, and it was harmful to the economy. So I just hope that whatever is done, it is done in a way that is confidence- inspiring. On insurance companies, we are going to do our best to tailor our consolidated supervision to insurance companies. But I agree with you that the Collins amendment does put some tough restrictions that-- Mr. Ross. Would you agree that we would have to legislate in order to give you--in other words-- Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Ross. Thank you. Because I think that where we are at and one of the reasons for the delay is that you can't put the capital requirements for banks as the minimum-level capital requirements for insurance companies. As was pointed out yesterday in a Wall Street Journal opinion article, you are going to see that the insurance companies are now going to be held to a higher capital standard, do more short-term debt. And now, all of a sudden, they may enter the banking business, which is going to be counterproductive to where we want to go with the correction that we are trying do. So my question to you, I guess, as a result is, if we impose the bank-centric capital requirements on insurance companies, would that have done anything to have saved AIG from its financial collapse of 5 years ago? Mr. Bernanke. There were a lot of things that AIG was doing that it couldn't do now. Let me just put it that way. Mr. Ross. Right. Mr. Bernanke. On the Collins amendment, it does make it more difficult for us, because it imposes, as you say, bank- style capital requirements on insurance companies. There are some things we can do, but it is providing some-- Mr. Ross. Would it be safe to say, in my last 20 seconds, that the future is not too bright for the nonbank financial institutions in terms of having any reduction in their capital requirements? Mr. Bernanke. There are some assets that insurance companies hold that we can differentially weight, for example. There are some things we can do. But, again, I think this does pose some difficulty for our oversight. Mr. Ross. Thank you. And thank you again for your service. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Washington, Mr. Heck. Mr. Heck. Thank you, sir. Mr. Chairman, given all the eulogies that have been delivered here today, at least on the Democratic side, I feel a little bit like Bette Midler, the very last guest on the very last episode of ``The Tonight Show'' that Johnny Carson hosted. She famously quipped to Mr. Carson, ``You are the wind beneath my wings.'' There is some application to you, sir, as it relates to the economy. And I thank you for your service, as well. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Mr. Heck. I also thank Mr. Ross for brilliantly anticipating where it is I wanted to go. I have to admit that, every day that goes by, I am increasingly less optimistic that I am a Member of an institution that can successfully deal with the debt limit. Sadly, I must admit that. I am wondering if failure by Congress to deal with it was one of the ``unanticipated shocks'' that you suggested our economy might be vulnerable to and, whether it is or not, what you would suggest about what the economic consequence would be if Congress does, in fact, fail to lift the debt limit later this early fall. Mr. Bernanke. I think it would be quite disruptive. It is important to understand that passing the extension of the debt limit is not approving new spending. What it is doing is approving payment for spending already incurred. So it would be very concerning for financial markets and, I think, for the general public if the United States didn't pay its bills. So I hope very much that particular issue can be resolved smoothly. I am not claiming in any way that it is not important to discuss these critical fiscal issues. It is. But to raise the prospect that the government won't pay its bills, including not just its interest on debt but even what it owes to seniors or to veterans or to contractors, is very concerning. And I think it could provide some shock to the economy if it got severely out of hand. Mr. Heck. Is there a material possibility that the shock would be so great as to be recession-inducing? Mr. Bernanke. Depending on how it plays out, I think, in particular, that a default by the U.S. Government would be extremely disruptive, yes. Mr. Heck. Secondly, and lastly, over the last couple of years the Fed has begun targeting interest rates on mortgages, in addition to your historic focus on baseline interest rate. Has the Fed considered, is the Fed considering, would the Fed consider implementing monetary policy through other credit channels either to minimize the possibility of an asset bubble or to target job creation, should we not see continued progress toward that lower unemployment rate that is desired by so many? Mr. Bernanke. The Federal Reserve actually is quite limited in what we can buy. We can basically buy Treasurys and government-guaranteed agency securities--that is, MBS. We are not allowed to buy corporate debt or other kinds of debt. So we don't really have the tools to address other types of credit. Mr. Heck. Setting aside for the moment that, if we fast- rewound ``X'' number of years, some people would probably have said the same thing about the activity you are exactly engaged in today, it was you, sir, who 11 years ago in a speech indicated that there might be other monetary policy options available to the Fed. It just does not seem to me to be much of anything other than a fairly easily adapted technical fix to allow you, for example, to engage in credit channels that, for example, back infrastructure. Infrastructure is something which, of course, is the gift that keeps on giving. But I don't see a legal impediment to you being able to venture into that area, as some would conclude you might have hinted back in 2002 before you were Chair and some might have suggested is a direct parallel to what you are doing today. Mr. Bernanke. I will put you in touch with our General Counsel. I don't think that is within our legal authorities. Mr. Heck. You would rule that out altogether? Mr. Bernanke. I don't see what the legal authority is to do that. Mr. Heck. Then I would like to have a conversation with your General Counsel. Mr. Bernanke. Okay. We will give you his number. Mr. Heck. And in the meantime, in 5 seconds, thank you, sir, very much. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has now expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Pittenger. Mr. Pittenger. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke. In response to an earlier question by Mr. Stivers regarding whether the Fed would be willing to conduct the same type of stress tests of its quantitative easing exit strategy that it has subjected financial institutions to, you stated that under a reasonable interest-rate scenario you would not expect any significant disruptions from the Fed's withdrawal of monetary stimulus. But the whole point of the stress test is to position an extremely adverse scenario, akin, say, to the inflation levels last seen in the late 1970s and early 1980s, not a reasonable interest-rate environment. Mr. Bernanke, has the Fed stress-tested its strategy according to that more extreme scenario? Mr. Bernanke. Again, this is not about our strategy; this is about our remittances to the Treasury. And when we do very tough interest-rate tests--and again, there are a number of them that have been published and are publicly available--what we see is, first, that even though there may be a period where remittances to the Treasury are low or zero, that over the 15- year period from 2009 to 2023, the total remittances generally are higher than they would have been in the case where there were no asset purchases. But I think you need to look beyond that, which is that to the extent that our asset purchases are strengthening the overall economy, that is very beneficial to the Treasury because of higher tax collections. And so I think most scholars who have looked at this conclude that the asset purchases are a winner for the taxpayer under almost all scenarios. Mr. Pittenger. Are you concerned by the perception, though, that the Fed will stress test the banks and other financial institutions but not review its own policies and strategies by the same rules? Mr. Bernanke. It is not comparable. The banks have credit risk. We have no credit risk. We buy only Treasurys and government-guaranteed MBS. So in a recession, we make money, because interest rates go down. Mr. Pittenger. Chairman Hensarling has shown up on the board the running debt clocks. Of concern to you, you have already expressed earlier, my friend for 20 years, Erskine Bowles, has run around the country, he and Alan Simpson were here last week, they rang the bell on the concerns relating to the debt. I want to get your thoughts on the policies that the Fed could lead to this compounding problem when it comes to the interest payments on the debt. Do you believe that when interest rates rise over the coming years, and the spending trajectory we are on towards the close of the decade, that the interest rates, along with annual deficits, could push America's debt to unsustainable levels, perhaps close to what we are seeing across Europe? That is really the thought that Erskine left with many of us. He said, ``I used to say this is for my grandchildren. Then I would say it is for my kids. Now I would say it is for me.'' And the urgency seems to be gone. President Obama has never mentioned it in the State of the Union, in his inauguration. It is the big elephant in the room that for some reason hasn't been there in terms of the focal point, and yet the interest rate, the interest requirements are going to be compounded this entire issue. How would you like to address that as we look ahead and foresee the outcomes that might achieve the same results that they have had in Europe? Mr. Bernanke. The CBO and the OMB, when they do the deficit projections, they assume that interest rates are going to rise. And if the economy recovers, interest rates should rise. That is part of a healthy recovery. So that is taken into account in their analysis. What their analysis finds is that, for the next 5 years or so, the debt-to-GDP ratio is fairly stable. But getting past into the next decade, then we start to see big imbalances arising mostly from long-term entitlement programs and a variety of other things, including interest payments. And so, as I have said on numerous occasions, I am all in favor of fiscal responsibility, but I think that in focusing only on the very near term and not the long term, you are sort of looking for the quarter where the lamppost is rather than looking for it where the quarter actually is. So that is my general view, that you should be looking at the longer-term fiscal situation. Mr. Pittenger. Straightening pictures while the house is burning down. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman is yielded back. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Kildee. Mr. Kildee. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke. I will just echo what many have said before. We certainly appreciate the great service that you have provided to this country. When you were here back in February, I was a mere freshman with 6 weeks' experience in Congress, and now I am a seasoned Member of Congress with almost 7 months. So I want to follow up on a line of questioning that I will take a minute or 2 to pursue. And I may not take my full 5 minutes; I may leave some time for others. But in your prepared remarks, you make some pretty important references. I think one of many that got my attention was the reference to improved financial positions of State and local governments. And while I think we all would acknowledge that is generally the case, I want to return to what will likely be my theme here for a long time, which is that there is great unevenness or inequity in the condition of municipal governments--State governments for sure, but municipal governments certainly. So I ask if you would mind perhaps commenting further. And, actually, in anticipation of not having time, I prepared a letter for you that I would like to submit and ask for your response. But if you think about it in the context of your dual mandate, the potential impact on regional economies and employment as an extension of what seems nearly certain to be severe financial stress for cities like Detroit--which, in many ways, is sort of a placeholder for what is a much bigger problem, and that is the disconnect between the presence of wealth and economic activity in America's legacy cities, older industrial cities, and the obligations that those cities have to sustainable regions. And so, sort of following on Mr. Heck's--although maybe not quite as far as Mr. Heck's comment regarding the reach of the Federal Reserve, I would ask if you would think about how you would advise Congress or how the Fed itself might pursue policy that would have the effect of potentially avoiding but certainly mitigating the economic effect of municipal financial failure. The one that always comes to mind first is the potential for municipal bond default, which could affect not only the creditworthiness of the municipality but obviously could have implications for State governments, since virtually all municipalities are creatures of State government, but, as importantly, the effect on the economic health of particular regions. I say this because, as I said back in February, I think this potentially is an institutional failure that is regionalized or localized but, for those places, is every bit as much and, I would argue, even more a threat than what we have seen with the financial distress that we faced back in the last half-decade and in the case of maybe the auto industry, what it faced. This is a serious pending crisis. I would just ask for your comments. And I will submit my letter for further response. Thank you. Mr. Bernanke. No. I agree that it is a very serious problem. If I am not mistaken, we have a Detroit City Manager on one of our local boards, and she has kept us informed about some of the projects that are being undertaken razing parts of the City and working on economic development and the like. So it is a very serious problem. I think as far as the Fed is concerned, there are two kinds of things we can do. First, obviously to solve the problem, you have to solve the underlying economic problem, and that means jobs, and that means economic growth, and our monetary policies are aimed at trying to achieve that. I think that is fundamental. Beyond that, we do have community development experts at the Fed. They work with community development groups, CDFIs and others, to try to reestablish an economic base in places that have been hollowed out for various reasons. And I recently--a few years ago, I guess it was, I went to Detroit and talked to suppliers, auto suppliers who provide input to the big companies to try to understand their economy. So I think that working through community groups, community organizations, CDFIs and the like to try to restore the economic base, that is the only long-run solution. You can provide help through the government in the short run, but unless the economy comes back, you don't really have a sustainable situation. Mr. Kildee. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Kentucky, Mr. Barr. Mr. Barr. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, thank you for your service and for your testimony here today. I have listened to your testimony and I have an observation, then a couple of questions. The observation is this: The Fed has held interest rates near zero for 4 years now. The Fed's balance sheet has more than tripled to $3.5 trillion and continues to grow. Today, you have testified that a highly accommodative policy will remain appropriate for the foreseeable future, and yet unemployment remains at 7.6 percent; 54 consecutive weeks of unemployment higher than 7\1/ 2\ percent; only 58 percent of the working-age population is employed; 5 straight years of declining wages; three-quarters of the American people are living paycheck to paycheck; and GDP growth remains well below the long-run average of 3 percent. All of this has happened coincident to a time when the role of government has grown dramatically as a percentage of our economy, higher taxes, stimulus spending, government bailouts, Obamacare, Dodd-Frank, skyrocketing compliance costs on financial institutions and crushing overregulation of the energy sector by the EPA. Given these realities and the Fed's extraordinary expansionary monetary policy, struggling American families are asking the following very important question: What is the cause of weakness and persistent weakness in our labor market? Is it the relative ineffectiveness of the Fed's monetary policy, or is it the fiscal policies like higher taxes, Obamacare, Dodd- Frank and overregulation by the EPA? My question is related to the exit strategy. During testimony in front of Congress last month, you refused to rule out tapering by the fall time period. The Federal Open Market Committee then released a statement that the Federal Reserve, ``will continue its purchases of Treasury mortgage-backed securities and employ its other policies as appropriate until the outlook for the labor market has improved substantially in the context of price stability.'' You have reiterated that today. These are hardly definitive statements about reducing the Fed's unprecedented and aggressive bond purchase program, yet the average 30-year, fixed-rate mortgage, as we have discussed earlier today, jumped by 42 basis points, the Dow suffered back-to-back declines of more than 200 points, and billions of dollars were traded out of credit funds after you said last month that the Fed could start winding down bond buying later this year. Given the sharp reaction of the credit markets to even the possibility of tapering, how will you prevent a catastrophic spike in interest rates when you actually do slow bond purchases? Mr. Bernanke. By communicating, by not surprising people, by letting them know what our plan is and how it relates to the economy. You talked about the weakness of the economy. I think that is evidence that we need to provide a continued accommodation, even if we begin to change over time the mix of tools that we use to provide that accommodation. You said a lot of correct things about the weakness of our economy. I agree with a lot of what you said. On the other hand, it is the case that we have made some progress since 2009, and many people think of the United States as one of the bright spots in the world. We are doing better than a lot of other industrial countries. And while we are certainly not where we want to be, at least we are going in the right direction, and we hope to support that. Mr. Barr. Given the persistent high unemployment, it seems to me that American families who are struggling, many of whom are in my district in eastern Kentucky, who continue to remain unemployed, persistently unemployed, and as you testified, the underemployment problem persists in this country, I think they justifiably have to ask themselves, given the expansionary policy that you have pursued quite aggressively, and to your credit, there has to be a fiscal policy problem here that has created this uncertainty. Let me conclude by bringing to your attention a quote that a commentator recently had to say about Fed policy, and I would like your reaction to it: ``If the economy begins to improve, and the Fed does not withdraw the tremendous reserves that it has created from the banking system, rampant inflation will follow. If it doesn't withdraw reserves quickly, interest rates will rise rapidly. This situation makes economic calculations extremely difficult and makes businesses less willing to invest, especially for the long term. If business owners could fully trust the Fed, this would not be an issue, but we have all been burned too many times to trust the Fed.'' Can you respond to that? Mr. Bernanke. There have been people saying we are going to have hyperinflation any day now for quite a while, and inflation is 1 percent. We know how to exit; we know how to do it without inflation. Of course, there is always a chance of going too early or too late and not hitting the sweet spot. That happens all the time whenever monetary policy tightens. But we have all the tools we need to exit without any concern about inflation. Mr. Barr. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chairman has graciously agreed to stay an extra 10 minutes, whether he knows it or not, notwithstanding the fact the problem was with our sound system. Without objection, I would like to recognize the remaining Members who are in the hearing room at this time for 2 minutes apiece. The gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr. Rothfus, is now recognized. Mr. Rothfus. Thank you. Chairman Bernanke, thank you for being here today. A simple question that I have is, when I have somebody in my district who is going to go out and buy a Treasury bill, that individual is looking to make an investment, they go to their bank, they go to their broker, they have $1,000, $5,000, and they get a bill. Where does the Fed get its money to buy its Treasury bills? Mr. Bernanke. When we buy securities from a private citizen, we create a deposit in the bank, their bank, and that shows up as reserves. So if you look at our balance sheet, our balance sheet balances, we have Treasury securities on the assets side. And liabilities side, we have either cash or reserves at banks, and that is what has been--on the margin, that is what has been building up is the excess reserves and-- Mr. Rothfus. You create the reserves? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Rothfus. And so, is that printing money? Mr. Bernanke. Not literally. Mr. Rothfus. Not literally. Mr. Bernanke. No. Mr. Rothfus. It is troubling me, when I look at the balance sheet that the Fed has, and I look at 4 years ago, it was $800 billion, and now we are up to $3.5 trillion. And I just--I know you say you are confident that you have the tools available to do a draw-down when necessary without risking hyperinflation, yet by your own admission, what you are doing is unprecedented. What assurance can you give to the American people that we are not going to have a round of rampant inflation 5 years down the road? Mr. Bernanke. It is not unprecedented, because many other central banks use similar tools to the ones that we plan to use. Mr. Rothfus. Currently? Or can you look back in history and see-- Mr. Bernanke. No. Mr. Rothfus. --somebody that has brought up its balance sheet by 311 percent in 4 years without any kind of negative consequence? Mr. Bernanke. Absolutely. Japan, Europe, and the U.K. have all done similar kinds of things with very large balance sheets. Mr. Rothfus. I appreciate your feedback on that, and we may reach out to you and get that information. Thank you. Mr. Bernanke. Sure. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from New Jersey, Mr. Garrett. Mr. Garrett. I thank the chairman. I thank Chairman Bernanke for our back-and-forth, what we have had over the years. So in 2 minutes, let me just run through a couple of questions, if I may. Right now with the balance sheet, as everyone has pointed out, at $3 trillion, I guess you stand as the world's largest bond fund manager. We have seen recently, since early May, a 1 percentage point spike in long-term Treasurys, right? If the Fed were to mark to market, can you tell us what the change in value of that fund is? Mr. Bernanke. It takes us from an $150 billion unrealized capital gain close to even. Mr. Garrett. One hundred fifty to eight hundred. Can you also then give us a rule of thumb going forward, because we have already heard progressions as to increases potentially today, tomorrow, or someday in the future as far as inflation. But if you do see further increases in that, maybe as a rule of thumb, illustrate the relationship between yields and the 10- year Treasury rates and the values of the bond fund. For example, what would the magnitude of losses be for every percentage point increase in long-term yields? Mr. Bernanke. I don't have a rule of thumb. I would refer you to the analyses that we published on this. It depends on the mix of maturities that we have and also the mix of Treasurys and MBS. Mr. Garrett. And do you compute that regularly to do-- Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Garrett. --to do that? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. And we publish it. Mr. Garrett. And so if we see a 2 or 3 percent, then what would that result in? Mr. Bernanke. I don't have a number for you. Mr. Garrett. All right. And in 20 seconds, right now during the week of September 13th, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and Ginnie Mae have been originating around $12.5 billion in debt. You have been purchasing around--or no, they have been generating about 11.4-. You have been purchasing around 12.5- in agency debt, which means a result of about 109 percent ratio there. Is there a problem there, and do you look at their originations going forward in your bond purchases? Mr. Bernanke. We are not seeing any problems in the MBS market, because we are not just buying new stuff, but old stuff as well. Mr. Garrett. Right. And I guess that is the point. Do you consider that when you do go forward or-- Chairman Hensarling. Time-- Mr. Garrett. Okay. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair recognizes the gentlelady from Minnesota, Mrs. Bachmann. Mrs. Bachmann. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here today. I note that in the daily Treasury statement for July 12th, the Fed debt subject to the legal limit was $16,699,000,000,000. It stood at exactly $16,699,396,000,000 for 56 straight days, defying all forces of nature, when we were accumulating about $4 billion a day in additional debt. And I note that just during part of the questioning, we have added over $400 million in debt, just in the time that you have talked to us today. So how could this freak of nature occur that the U.S. Treasury would report for 56 straight days that the debt stayed at $16,699,000,000,000? Has the Federal Government been cooking the books for these 56 days in a row, or what happened? Mr. Bernanke. That is not the Federal Reserve. You would have to ask the Secretary of the Treasury. Mrs. Bachmann. Could you comment on that? Mr. Bernanke. I don't know what the issue is. I would have to look at the numbers and what they refer to. Mrs. Bachmann. This was reported at CNS.com, but it is on the Treasury statement for July 12th. Were you aware of this-- Mr. Bernanke. No. Mrs. Bachmann. --that the debt stayed, by some freak coincidence, at this level? Mr. Bernanke. Maybe it has to do with the use of unusual special measures to deal with the debt limit. There are various things they can do, to give some extra space. Maybe that is what is happening, so it is not being counted in the debt. Ms. Bachmann. That is what was reported in the news, that this is an extraordinary action, but to the common American citizen this clearly looks like the Federal Government is cooking the books. Mr. Bernanke. They are using--as you know, whenever the debt limit comes close, Treasury Departments under both parties have used a variety of different accounting devices to give some extra headroom, some extra space. Mrs. Bachmann. Have we exceeded our debt limit? Mr. Bernanke. I don't think so. Mrs. Bachmann. Thank you. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The last questioner will be the gentleman from New Mexico, Mr. Pearce. You are recognized. Mr. Pearce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. You almost beat the clock. I appreciate you staying around. As you remember, last time you were here I gave you an invitation to come to New Mexico and explain to seniors about your policy. And we have also talked a couple of times. The group is still gathering out there, we are trucking them in for lunches, so if you ever decide to come to New Mexico to have that meeting-- Mr. Perlmutter actually headed down this direction. You continue to take advantage of seniors because they don't have access to sophisticated instruments, so a lot of them have their money in cash or near cash equivalents. Now, Mr. Perlmutter noted that the home financing has increased by from 3.3 to 4.5. We have a whole sheaf of Wall Street profit reports. Those are growing extraordinarily high. Did the seniors even get kind of a mention, an honorable mention, in the question about who is going to pay the bill for this? When are you going to start going up on the interest rate just a little bit? Because right now you are taking from seniors, and you are giving to Wall Street, basically. In my district we are, like, 43rd per capita income, $14,000 to $18,000 per year. Seniors live their life right. They paid off their bills, and they are being punished for this economy. Mr. Bernanke. Again, I don't think the Fed can get interest rates up very much, because the economy is weak, inflation rates are low. If we were to tighten policy, the economy would tank, and interest rates would be low. Mr. Pearce. These guys are making record rates. They just went up a percent and a half. Their costs are not going up. One last question, as we run out of time. I was interested in the Republican obstructionism comments earlier. I am wondering why the Democrats didn't do anything from 2009 to 2010 on immigration. Considering the multipliers that came in 1986, they thought it was 1 million, they legalized 3.3 million--3.5 million, they brought 5- with them. That is 16 million. If we get that multiple, 150 million people could be here. Is there a number at which the economy is adversely affected? Mr. Bernanke. I don't know. Mr. Pearce. Thank you, sir. I will yield back. Chairman Hensarling. All time has expired. I want to thank Chairman Bernanke again for his testimony today. The Chair notes that some Members may have additional questions for this witness, which they may wish to submit in writing. Without objection, the hearing record will remain open for 5 legislative days for Members to submit written questions to this witness and to place his responses in the record. Also, without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit extraneous materials to the Chair for inclusion in the record. This hearing is now adjourned. [Whereupon, at 1:15 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X July 17, 2013 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]