[House Hearing, 113 Congress] [From the U.S. Government Publishing Office] MONETARY POLICY AND THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY ======================================================================= HEARING BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES ONE HUNDRED THIRTEENTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION __________ FEBRUARY 27, 2013 __________ Printed for the use of the Committee on Financial Services Serial No. 113-3 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT] U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 80-869 PDF WASHINGTON : 2013 ----------------------------------------------------------------------- For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512-1800; DC area (202) 512-1800 Fax: (202) 512-2104 Mail: Stop IDCC, Washington, DC 20402-0001 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL SERVICES JEB HENSARLING, Texas, Chairman GARY G. MILLER, California, Vice MAXINE WATERS, California, Ranking Chairman Member SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama, Chairman CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York Emeritus NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York PETER T. KING, New York MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina EDWARD R. ROYCE, California BRAD SHERMAN, California FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma GREGORY W. MEEKS, New York SHELLEY MOORE CAPITO, West Virginia MICHAEL E. CAPUANO, Massachusetts SCOTT GARRETT, New Jersey RUBEN HINOJOSA, Texas RANDY NEUGEBAUER, Texas WM. LACY CLAY, Missouri PATRICK T. McHENRY, North Carolina CAROLYN McCARTHY, New York JOHN CAMPBELL, California STEPHEN F. LYNCH, Massachusetts MICHELE BACHMANN, Minnesota DAVID SCOTT, Georgia KEVIN McCARTHY, California AL GREEN, Texas STEVAN PEARCE, New Mexico EMANUEL CLEAVER, Missouri BILL POSEY, Florida GWEN MOORE, Wisconsin MICHAEL G. FITZPATRICK, KEITH ELLISON, Minnesota Pennsylvania ED PERLMUTTER, Colorado LYNN A. WESTMORELAND, Georgia JAMES A. HIMES, Connecticut BLAINE LUETKEMEYER, Missouri GARY C. PETERS, Michigan BILL HUIZENGA, Michigan JOHN C. CARNEY, Jr., Delaware SEAN P. DUFFY, Wisconsin TERRI A. SEWELL, Alabama ROBERT HURT, Virginia BILL FOSTER, Illinois MICHAEL G. GRIMM, New York DANIEL T. KILDEE, Michigan STEVE STIVERS, Ohio PATRICK MURPHY, Florida STEPHEN LEE FINCHER, Tennessee JOHN K. DELANEY, Maryland MARLIN A. STUTZMAN, Indiana KYRSTEN SINEMA, Arizona MICK MULVANEY, South Carolina JOYCE BEATTY, Ohio RANDY HULTGREN, Illinois DENNY HECK, Washington DENNIS A. ROSS, Florida ROBERT PITTENGER, North Carolina ANN WAGNER, Missouri ANDY BARR, Kentucky TOM COTTON, Arkansas Shannon McGahn, Staff Director James H. Clinger, Chief Counsel C O N T E N T S ---------- Page Hearing held on: February 27, 2013............................................ 1 Appendix: February 27, 2013............................................ 57 WITNESSES Wednesday, February 27, 2013 Bernanke, Hon. Ben S., Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System......................................... 6 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Ross, Hon. Dennis............................................ 58 Bernanke, Hon. Ben S......................................... 61 Additional Material Submitted for the Record Bernanke, Hon. Ben S.: Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, dated February 26, 2013....................................................... 71 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Bachus..................................................... 129 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Fitzpatrick................................................ 133 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Garrett.................................................... 135 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Maloney.................................................... 142 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Mulvaney................................................... 147 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Ross....................................................... 150 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Royce...................................................... 152 Written responses to questions submitted by Representative Stivers.................................................... 162 MONETARY POLICY AND THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY ---------- Wednesday, February 27, 2013 U.S. House of Representatives, Committee on Financial Services, Washington, D.C. The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Jeb Hensarling [chairman of the committee] presiding. Members present: Representatives Hensarling, Miller, Bachus, Royce, Capito, Garrett, Neugebauer, McHenry, Campbell, Bachmann, Pearce, Posey, Fitzpatrick, Westmoreland, Luetkemeyer, Huizenga, Duffy, Hurt, Grimm, Stivers, Fincher, Stutzman, Mulvaney, Hultgren, Ross, Pittenger, Wagner, Barr, Cotton; Waters, Maloney, Velazquez, Watt, Sherman, Meeks, Capuano, Hinojosa, Clay, McCarthy of New York, Scott, Green, Cleaver, Moore, Ellison, Perlmutter, Himes, Peters, Carney, Sewell, Foster, Kildee, Murphy, Delaney, Sinema, Beatty, and Heck. Chairman Hensarling. The committee will come to order. Without objection, the Chair is authorized to declare a recess of the committee at any time. The Chair now recognizes himself for an opening statement. We are clearly in the midst of the slowest and weakest recovery in the post-war era, notwithstanding what we have observed to be the largest fiscal and monetary stimulus in our Nation's history. Although one quarter does not make a trend, having negative economic growth in the last quarter was not good news. Otherwise, we appear to be mired in 1\1/2\ to 2 percent economic growth, when 3 percent is the norm and, clearly, 4 percent is the potential. This translates into millions of lost jobs and hundreds of billions of dollars of lost revenue to the Treasury. But beyond the numbers, we have to look at the people. I look at my constituents, I listen to them. They are concerned about how they are going to fill up their pickup trucks, and how they are going to afford groceries. Their health care premiums have gone up. They are insecure in their paychecks. They are not getting ahead. So as we welcome Chairman Bernanke back for his semiannual Humphrey-Hawkins testimony before our committee, many wonder, where do we find the road forward? After quadrupling its balance sheet, engaging in unprecedented mortgage-backed security asset purchases, and creating an extended negative real interest rate environment, there is a growing consensus among economists that the Federal Reserve's road has led us to the monetary ``Outer Limits.'' And if one remembers that classic science fiction television program, typically the episodes did not end well. They did not have happy endings, and I fear this may prove true for the current Federal Reserve policy. For diminishing marginal benefits, the Federal Reserve's unconventional strategy creates considerable risk. If the balance sheet is not unwound at the right time and at the right pace, we could be looking at another deep recession, soaring inflation, or skyrocketing interest rates, all of which could make us look longingly and nostalgically upon the Jimmy Carter era of stagflation. All central bankers are familiar with Walter Bagehot's dictum of the central bank's lender-of-last-resort function, ``Lend freely at a high rate on good collateral.'' Many of us believe the Fed has gone way beyond that. The extraordinary measures of 2008 appear to have become the ordinary measures of 2013. Walter Bagehot also said, ``What impresses men is not mind, but the result of mind.'' And although the Federal Reserve contains many impressive minds and many impressive public servants, currently millions of unemployed and underemployed Americans are not impressed with the results. I believe that is because today the economic challenges of our nature are essentially fiscal in nature, not monetary. They cannot be solved by the Fed. The reasons that the Nation is mired in the slowest, weakest recovery in the post-war era are simple. Under this President, we have seen a 53 percent increase in job-harming Federal tape and regulations. They tend to fall into two categories: those that create uncertainty; and those that create certain harm. Under this President, we have witnessed a spending spree, including the $1 trillion failed stimulus that has grown government from 20 percent of GDP to 24 percent. Under this President, a long-threatened $1.6 trillion tax increase has just been imposed upon small businesses and many working families. And under this President, more debt has been created in 4 years on a nominal basis than in our Nation's first 200 years, now weighing in at approximately $136,000 per household. So let's examine the tale of two recoveries. The 1981-1982 recession was deeper in terms of GDP contraction, and unemployment was higher, and the recession was similar in its financial nature. And, in this case, the economy faced a dramatic contractionary monetary policy that pushed interest rates over 20 percent. Yet, because President Reagan ushered in a pro-growth tax relief, established budget discipline, relieved much of the burden of foolish red tape, and promoted and celebrated free-market capitalism, we witnessed one of the quickest and most powerful recoveries in the Nation's history. President Obama and the U.S. Senate could certainly profit from this example. Again, today, our challenges are primarily fiscal in nature, not monetary. Finally, as I close, since I know both the Chairman and many Members will speak to the pending sequester, I have no doubt that our President is quite capable of designing the meager budget savings represented in the sequester in such a way as to maximize pain to the American people. But as a matter of fact, even after the sequester, government outlays will be $15 billion more next year, and 30 percent greater than the year President Obama was first elected. Meanwhile, the national debt clock to my right and to my left continues to spin out of control, threatening our national security, our economic recovery, and our children's future. I now recognize the ranking member for 5 minutes for an opening statement. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I am very appreciative for the fact that you are holding this hearing. But before I begin my statement today, I would like to take a moment to recognize Mr. Dave Smith, the chief economist of the Democratic staff of the Financial Services Committee, who will be retiring at the end of this week. Dave has been an invaluable resource to the members of this committee, and we will certainly miss having his counsel and guidance. We thank him for his dedication and extensive service and wish him all the best in his future endeavors. Mr. Dave Smith. [applause] Chairman Hensarling. Can you please restart the clock for the ranking member? Ms. Waters. And, with that, I am very pleased to welcome Chairman Bernanke before the committee to present his report on the conduct of monetary policy and the state of the economy, as required twice a year by the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. First, I would like to commend Chairman Bernanke for his leadership and bold efforts, in cooperation with the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), to foster the conditions that stimulate lending, economic activity, and private sector job creation. While some have expressed concerns about the potential risk involved in the Fed's aggressive quantitative easing programs, I sincerely believe our central bank's actions have provided critical support for our Nation's economic recovery. In fact, the Fed's intervention may be one of the few actions protecting that recovery from some of my colleagues' ongoing pursuit of retractionary fiscal policies. As we sit here today, yet another manufactured fiscal crisis looms due to sequestration's automatic spending cuts that are scheduled to take effect in just 2 days. And despite those who wish to downplay the impact of sequestration, the costs are real. The CBO estimates that 750,000 jobs are at stake in 2013. The Bipartisan Policy Center projects the loss of at least a million jobs over the next 2 years. And a recent George Mason University study put the number at 2.14 million jobs, over 950,000 of which would be attributable to losses by small businesses. It is my hope that both Republicans and Democrats can come together to construct a more balanced approach to addressing the deficit while protecting our Nation's ongoing recovery from the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. With that in mind, I wanted to use this opportunity to note a GAO report released last month which outlined the enormous cost of the financial crisis to the U.S. economy. The GAO found that the financial crisis' impact on economic output could be as much as $13 trillion, and, in addition, the amount of home equity wealth lost by U.S. homeowners reached $9.1 trillion. And this is precisely why I believe it is imperative that we fully implement the regulatory reforms within the Wall Street Reform Act in order to ensure that we never again experience a crisis like the one that occurred in 2008. I look forward to Chairman Bernanke's insight on all of these matters and, in particular, his perspective on how the automatic spending cuts scheduled to take effect this week will impact our Nation's recovery and economic growth. Mr. Bernanke, members of this committee, and Chairman Hensarling, I would like you to know that I take these Humphrey-Hawkins reports that are done twice a year seriously. As many of you know, Gus Hawkins was my predecessor. And when I ran for office, I ran for office at the time that Gus Hawkins was getting involved with this dual mandate that is the essence of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. We know that Mr. Hawkins was concerned about jobs and he was concerned about monetary policy. And because of his concern, he worked very hard with Senator Hubert Humphrey to make sure that jobs and monetary policy played an important role in the deliberations and the debate and the discussions that go on in the Congress of the United States of America. And so, as we are faced with sequestration, we must understand the negative impact that sequestration and these cuts will have on jobs and the economy. And your being here today, Mr. Bernanke, is extremely important, because no one knows better than you about the impact of sequestration and what it will do to our jobs and our jobs potential in this country and, of course, the monetary policy that you have so creatively and so expertly guided to help get us back on the road to growth. And without what you are doing, we would not have maintained growth, slow as it may be, without what you have done and your leadership. I thank you very much. And I yield back the balance of my time. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the chairman of the Monetary Policy and Trade Subcommittee, the gentleman from California, Mr. Campbell, for 3 minutes. Mr. Campbell. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And welcome, Chairman Bernanke. You said yesterday, and you will say today, that you believe the short-term benefits of the current loose monetary policy exceed the longer-term risks. We know from the release of the Federal Open Market Committee minutes last week that there is some dissension within the FOMC on that viewpoint. I am going to join in the chorus of dissension about that viewpoint. And I would like to just quickly detail seven risks that I believe exist which, together, are exceeding what I believe are now the meager benefits of the current monetary policy. First of all, there are bubbles out there. I would argue that there is one in high-yield bonds, perhaps in farmland, and certainly in the Federal budget. Second, where there are not bubbles, there are distortions, as people are having a difficulty pricing risk, and there are distortions in the economy. When these bubbles and distortions unwind, those are going to create problems. Third, I hear all the time that the major investment and business strategy now is, don't fight the Fed. That is not a real business strategy. That is not looking out at long-term vision. That is not making decisions on where you think markets will go. That is simply following the directive of an agency that unfortunately has too great a footprint, in my opinion, in the economy today. Fourth, all of this is actually not injecting certainty but, in my view, injecting uncertainty into decision-making in the economy today. Fifth, savers and retirees are being forced into riskier assets in the search for some sort of yield. When this unwinds, that is going to be a problem for our savers and retirees. We all in economics learned early on, as you get older, take less risk. But now what we find is as people are getting older, they are having to violate that principle, and in search of some kind of yield, are taking much, much greater risks, which could be a problem in the future. Sixth, for every 1 percent that the interest rates on Treasury bills go up, it will add $1 billion of deficit to the Federal budget. And, seventh, the Federal Reserve itself has risks now, with the large balance sheet and the large number of holdings that the Federal Reserve has. In this Member's opinion, Mr. Chairman, we have gone too far in the monetary policy and the monetary easing, and it is, in this Member's opinion, time to pull back. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. The Chair now recognizes the ranking member of the Monetary Policy and Trade Subcommittee, the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Clay, for 3 minutes. Mr. Clay. Thank you, Chairman Hensarling, for holding this hearing on monetary policy and the state of the economy. Also, thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for appearing today. The Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, better known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, set four benchmarks for the economy: full employment; growth in production; price stability; and the balance of trade and budget. To monitor progress toward these goals, the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978 mandated that the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System present semiannual reports to Congress on the state of the U.S. economy and the Nation's financial welfare. Humphrey-Hawkins charges the Federal Reserve with a dual mandate: maintaining stable prices; and full employment. Currently, the unemployment rate is 7.9 percent, down from 8.3 percent a year ago. Still, millions in this country would like to work but cannot find work. Consumer price inflation has increased as prices of consumer food and energy have increased from the pace seen in previous months. Recent price increases in retail gasoline have increased the cost of food. All of these factors play a very important role in getting America back to economic growth and prosperity. And I look forward to Chairman Bernanke's comments. Mr. Chairman, I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The gentleman yields back. At this time, we will welcome our distinguished witness, one of Washington's ablest public servants, Ben Bernanke, the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. And, as the phrase goes, he needs no further introduction. Chairman Bernanke, you will be recognized for 5 minutes to give an oral presentation of your written testimony. Without objection, your written statement will be made a part of the record. Once you have finished presenting, each Member of the committee will have 5 minutes within which to ask any or all questions. I wish to inform all Members that Chairman Bernanke will be allowed to exit at 1 p.m., and this chairman will ride the gavel accordingly. So if you ask a question with 10 seconds to go on the clock, do not expect an answer. On the Republican side, I wish to inform our Members that, should you not be able to ask questions of the Chairman today, you will receive priority at the Chairman's next appearance before our committee. Chairman Bernanke, at this time, please proceed. STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE BEN S. BERNANKE, CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM Mr. Bernanke. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, Ranking Member Waters, and members of the committee. I am pleased to present the Federal Reserve's semiannual monetary policy report. I will begin with a short summary of current economic conditions and then discuss aspects of monetary and fiscal policy. Since I last reported to this committee in mid-2012, economic activity in the United States has continued at a moderate, if somewhat uneven, pace. In particular, real GDP is estimated to have risen at an annual rate of about 3 percent in the third quarter but to have been essentially flat in the fourth quarter. The pause in real GDP growth last quarter does not appear to reflect a stalling out of the recovery. Rather, economic activity was temporarily restrained by weather-related disruptions and by transitory declines in a few volatile categories of spending, even as demand by U.S. households and businesses continued to expand. Available information suggests that economic growth has picked up again this year. Consistent with the moderate pace of economic growth, conditions in the labor market have been improving gradually. Since July, non-farm payroll employment has increased by 175,000 jobs per month on average and the unemployment rate has declined three-tenths of a percentage point to 7.9 percent over the same period. Cumulatively, private sector payrolls have now grown by about 6.1 million jobs since their low point in early 2010 and the unemployment rate has fallen a bit more than 2 percentage points since its cyclical peak in late 2009. Despite these gains, however, the job market remains generally weak, with the unemployment rate well above its longer-run normal level. About 4.7 million of the unemployed have been without a job for 6 months or more, and millions more would like full-time employment but are able to find only part- time work. High unemployment has substantial costs, including not only the hardship faced by the unemployed and their families but also the harm done to the vitality and productive potential of our economy as a whole. Lengthy periods of unemployment and underemployment can erode workers' skills and attachment to the labor force or prevent young people from gaining skills and experience in the first place, developments that could significantly reduce their productivity and earnings in the longer term. The loss of output and earnings associated with high unemployment also reduces government revenue and increases spending, thereby leading to larger deficits and debts. The recent increase in gasoline prices, which reflects both higher crude oil prices and wider refining margins, is hitting family budgets. However, overall inflation remains low. Over the second half of 2012, the price index for personal consumption expenditures rose at an annual rate of 1\1/2\ percent, similar to the rate of increase in the first half of the year. Measures of longer-term inflation expectations have remained in the narrow ranges seen over the past several years. Against this backdrop, the FOMC anticipates that inflation over the medium term will likely run at or below its 2 percent objective. With unemployment well above normal levels and inflation subdued, progress toward the Federal Reserve's mandated objectives of maximum employment and price stability has required a highly accommodative monetary policy. Under normal circumstances, policy accommodation would be provided through reductions in the FOMC's target for the Federal funds rate, the interest rate on overnight loans between banks. However, as this rate has been close to zero since December 2008, the Federal Reserve has had to use alternative policy tools. These alternative tools have fallen into two categories. The first is forward guidance regarding the FOMC's anticipated path for the Federal funds rate. At its December 2012 meeting, the FOMC provided more explicit guidance on how it expects the policy rate to respond to economic developments. Specifically, the December post- meeting statement indicated that the current exceptionally low range for the Federal funds rates ``will be appropriate as long as the unemployment rate remains above 6\1/2\ percent, inflation between 1 and 2 years ahead is projected to be no more than half a percentage point above the Committee's 2 percent longer-run goal, and longer-term inflation expectations continue to be well-anchored.'' An advantage of the new formulation relative to the previous date-based guidance is that it allows market participants and the public to update their monetary policy expectations more accurately in response to new information about the economic outlook. The new guidance also serves to underscore the Committee's intention to maintain accommodation as long as needed to promote a stronger economic recovery with stable prices. The second type of nontraditional policy tool employed by the FOMC is large-scale purchases of longer-term securities, which, like our forward guidance, are intended to support economic growth by putting downward pressure on longer-term interest rates. The Federal Reserve has engaged in several rounds of such purchases since 2008. Last September, the FOMC announced that it would purchase agency mortgage-backed securities at a pace of $40 billion per month. And in December, the Committee stated that, in addition, beginning in January, it would purchase longer-term Treasury securities at an initial pace of $45 billion per month. These additional purchases of longer-term Treasury securities replace the purchases we were conducting under our now-completed Maturity Extension Program, which lengthened the maturity of our securities portfolio without increasing its size. The FOMC has indicated that it will continue purchases until it observes a substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market in a context of price stability. The Committee also stated that in determining the size, pace, and composition of its asset purchases, it will take appropriate account of their likely efficacy and costs. In other words, as with all of its policy decisions, the Committee continues to assess its program of asset purchases within a cost-benefit framework. In the current economic environment, the benefits of asset purchases and of policy accommodation more generally are clear. Monetary policy is providing important support to the recovery while keeping inflation close to the FOMC's 2 percent objective. Notably, keeping longer-term interest rates low has helped spark recovery in the housing market and led to increased sales and production of automobiles and other durable goods. By raising employment and household wealth--for example, through higher home prices--these developments have, in turn, supported consumer sentiment and spending. Highly accommodative monetary policy also has several potential costs and risks, which the Committee is monitoring closely. For example, if further expansion of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet were to undermine public confidence in our ability to exit smoothly from our accommodative policies at the appropriate time, inflation expectations could rise, putting the FOMC's price stability objective at risk. However, the Committee remains confident that it has the tools necessary to tighten monetary policy when the time comes to do so. As I noted, inflation is currently subdued and inflation expectations appear well-anchored. Neither the FOMC nor private forecasters are projecting the development of significant inflation pressures. Another potential cost that the Committee takes very seriously is the possibility that very low interest rates, if maintained for a considerable time, could impair financial stability. For example, portfolio managers dissatisfied with low returns may reach for yield by taking on more credit risk, duration risk, or leverage. On the other hand, some risk- taking, such as when an entrepreneur takes out a loan to start a new business or an existing firm expands capacity, is a necessary element of a healthy economic recovery. Moreover, although accommodative monetary policies may increase certain types of risk-taking, in the present circumstances they also serve in some ways to reduce risk in the system, most importantly by strengthening the overall economy, but also by encouraging firms to rely more on longer- term funding and by reducing debt service costs for households and businesses. In any case, the Federal Reserve is responding actively to financial stability concerns through substantially expanded monitoring of emerging risks in the financial system, an approach to the supervision of financial firms that takes a more systemic perspective, and the ongoing implementation of reforms to make the financial system more transparent and resilient. Although a long period of low rates could encourage excessive risk-taking, and continued close attention to such developments is certainly warranted, to this point we do not see the potential cost of the increased risk-taking in some financial markets as outweighing the benefits of promoting a stronger economic recovery and more rapid job creation. Another aspect of the Federal Reserve's policies that has been discussed is their implications for the Federal budget. The Federal Reserve earns substantial interest on the assets it holds in its portfolio, and other than the amount needed to fund our cost of operations, all net income is remitted to the Treasury. With the expansion of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, yearly remittances have roughly tripled in recent years, with payments to the Treasury totaling approximately $290 billion between 2009 and 2012. However, if the economy continues to strengthen, as we anticipate, and policy accommodation is accordingly reduced, these remittances will likely decline in coming years. Federal Reserve analysis shows that remittances to the Treasury could be quite low for a time in some scenarios, particularly if interest rates were to rise quickly. However, even in such scenarios, it is highly likely that average annual remittances over the period affected by the Federal Reserve's purchases will remain higher than the pre- crisis norm, perhaps substantially so. Moreover, to the extent that monetary policy promotes growth and job creation, the resulting reduction in the Federal deficit would dwarf any variation in the Federal Reserve's remittances to the Treasury. Mr. Chairman, I have a couple more pages on fiscal policy. Will you allow me to complete it, or should I stop? Chairman Hensarling. You can proceed, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Although monetary policy is working to promote a more robust recovery, it cannot carry the entire burden of ensuring a speedier return to economic health. The economy's performance, both over the near term and in the longer run, will depend importantly on the course of fiscal policy. The challenge for the Congress and the Administration is to put the Federal budget on a sustainable long-run path that promotes economic growth and stability without unnecessarily impeding the current recovery. Significant progress has been made recently toward reducing the Federal budget deficit over the next few years. The projections released earlier this month by the CBO indicate that under current law, the Federal deficit will narrow from 7 percent of GDP last year to 2\1/2\ percent in Fiscal Year 2015. As a result, the Federal debt held by the public, including that held by the Federal Reserve, is projected to remain roughly 75 percent of GDP through much of the current decade. However, a substantial portion of the recent progress in lowering the deficit has been concentrated in near-term budget changes, which, taken together, could create a significant headwind for the economic recovery. The CBO estimates that deficit-reduction policies in current law will slow the pace of real GDP growth by about 1\1/2\ percentage points this year relative to what it would have been otherwise. A significant portion of this effect is related to the automatic spending sequestration that is scheduled to begin on March 1st, which, according to the CBO's estimates, will contribute about six-tenths of a percentage point to the fiscal drag on economic growth this year. Given the still moderate underlying pace of economic growth, this additional near-term burden on the recovery is significant. Moreover, besides having adverse effects on jobs and income, a slower recovery would lead to less actual deficit reduction in the short run for any given set of fiscal actions. At the same time, and despite progress in reducing near- term budget deficits, the difficult process of addressing longer-term fiscal imbalances has only begun. Indeed, the CBO projects that the Federal deficit and debt as a percentage of GDP will begin rising again in the latter half of this decade, reflecting in large part the aging of the population and fast- rising health care costs. To promote economic growth in the longer term, and to preserve economic and financial stability, fiscal policymakers will have to put the Federal budget on a sustainable long-run path that first stabilizes the ratio of Federal debt to GDP and, given the current elevated level of debt, eventually places that ratio on a downward trajectory. Between 1960 and the onset of the financial crisis, Federal debt averaged less than 40 percent of GDP. This relatively low level of debt provided the Nation much-needed flexibility to meet the economic challenges of the past few years. Replenishing this fiscal capacity will give future Congresses and Administrations greater scope to deal with unforeseen events. To address both the near- and longer-term issues, the Congress and the Administration should consider replacing the sharp, front-loaded spending cuts required by the sequestration with policies that reduce the Federal deficit more gradually in the near term but more substantially in the longer run. Such an approach could lessen the near-term fiscal headwinds facing the recovery while more effectively addressing the longer-term imbalances in the Federal budget. The sizes of deficits and debt matter, of course, but not all tax and spending programs are created equal with respect to their effects on the economy. To the greatest extent possible, in their efforts to achieve sound public finances, fiscal policymakers should not lose sight of the need for Federal tax and spending policies that increase incentives to work and save, encourage investment and workforce skills, advance private capital formation, promote research and development, and provide necessary and productive public infrastructure. Although economic growth alone cannot eliminate Federal budget imbalances in either the short or longer term, a more rapidly expanding economic pie will ease the difficult choices we face. Thank you for your indulgence, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Chairman Bernanke can be found on page 61 of the appendix.] Chairman Hensarling. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And the Chair will now recognize himself for 5 minutes for questions. Chairman Bernanke, I have both privately and publicly complimented you and the Fed for much of what you did in 2008, but, as you heard in my opening statement, I have a great fear that the extraordinary has become ordinary and, indeed, we need to examine these policies in, as you put it, a cost-benefit framework. So, briefly, I want to inquire about the risks, the benefits, and the cost. In your testimony, you said, ``The Committee remains confident that it has the tools necessary to tighten monetary policy when the time comes to do so.'' But, Mr. Chairman, I think you know that other predictions have not proven valid. In May of 2006, you seemed to be confident that we were witnessing ``an orderly decline in the housing market,'' and in 2007 you predicted ``a soft landing for the economy,'' neither of which happened. The Fed has been fairly off on its GDP projections, and as of 2 months ago, you stated, ``Well, I think it is fair to say that we have overestimated the pace of growth.'' So, Chairman Bernanke, I guess I recall Casey Stengel's quote, ``Never make predictions, especially about the future.'' I assume you will admit to being human and being fallible? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, sir. Chairman Hensarling. So that causes some of us to question how much confidence we should have. And as the gentleman from California, Mr. Campbell, pointed out, it is not just members of this committee, but apparently the voices of doubt and dissent within the Fed are growing more vocal. Jeffrey Lacker, President of the Richmond Fed: ``I think that further monetary stimulus is unlikely to materially increase the pace of economic expansion and that these actions will test the limits of our credibility.'' Bloomberg has reported of Charles Plosser, Philadelphia Fed President: ``Plosser said he favored halting additional bond purchases because their benefits are pretty meager and there are lots of risk.'' Closer to home, Richard Fisher, President of the Dallas Fed: ``I will be asking myself, what good would it do to buy more mortgage-backed securities or more treasuries when we have so much money sitting on the sidelines and yet have no sense of direction for the future of the Federal Government's tax and spending policy? How could additional monetary policy be stimulative?'' I clearly believe you disagree with these Fed Presidents; is that correct? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, sir. Chairman Hensarling. Let's examine the benefits of your current policy. Again, we know we are in a slow and weak recovery. Here is the question I have, Mr. Chairman. According to Fed data, banks are sitting on $1.6 trillion in excess reserves, and in the latest quarter for which I have data, the third quarter of 2012, non-financial corporations are sitting on $1.7 trillion in liquid assets. So, arguably, that is over $3 trillion of capital sitting on the sidelines. I believe I have this right, at least for the last data I have on, I believe, QE2: 80 percent of that QE ended up as excess reserves. So, given as much capital is sitting on the sidelines and since we are essentially in a zero to negative real interest rate environment, why do you believe that further quantitative easing is somehow going to cause entrepreneurs and job creators to put all this capital to work? Mr. Bernanke. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First, on the disagreements on the committee, we have our debates more or less in public, as you know. And I hope you would take some comfort from the fact that a wide range of views and points of view are represented on the committee. And we-- Chairman Hensarling. I do take solace, and I hope you listen to them carefully. Mr. Bernanke. And we do discuss all these issues. Of course, the significant majority of the committee is supportive of the policies that we are taking. You are absolutely also right that predicting the future is always dangerous. But we are not talking here about a forecast of the future. What we are talking about are the tools that we have to unwind the balance sheet. And we have a variety of different tools, including not just selling assets, but raising the interest rate we pay on excess reserves and the use of other draining tools, which, based on the experience of other central banks, would be effective in allowing us to unwind that policy. Of course, doing it at the exact right moment is always difficult, but-- Chairman Hensarling. Chairman, I am about out of time. I am going to attempt to set a good example here. I want to ask one last question, but you can submit the answer in writing. You mentioned earlier that--or as I understand it from data or reports from the Fed--you will cease remitting profits to the U.S. Treasury and that, under your own analysis, the size of deferred assets--I am always curious how a loss is a deferred asset--could peak at $120 billion, but other economists say it is closer to $372 billion of taxpayer money that could exacerbate the debt. So, in writing, I would like for you to respond whether or not, indeed, the debt could be exacerbated by $372 billion under a worst-case scenario. At this time, I will recognize the ranking member for 5 minutes. Ms. Waters. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Again, Mr. Bernanke, I would like to thank you for further explaining and educating this committee on quantitative easing, the policy that you have provided leadership on. And I would like to make sure that the members of this committee understand that this discussion about all of this dissent is overblown. As I look at the voting on this action, it appears that you, Mr. Bernanke--William C. Dudley, James Bullard, Elizabeth Duke, Charles L. Evans, Jerome H. Powell, Sarah Bloom Raskin, Eric Rosengren, Jeremy C. Stein, Daniel K. Tarullo, and Janet L. Yellen all voted to support you and the policies. There was only one person dissenting, and that was Esther George. So it seems to me you have strong support for the actions that you are taking and the leadership that you are giving. And I am very appreciative for that. I am surprised at myself for the confidence and support that I am showing, because you know I have disagreed with you in the past on a number of things. But I also find myself a little bit surprised that I am focused a lot on what happened with a recent research note that was released last Friday by the Bank of America's chief economist, Ethan Harris, where he warned that harsh budget cuts due to start taking effect this week would hammer the economy, potentially dragging the country back down into a recession. Mr. Harris wrote that he expects this painful shot of austerity to slow GDP growth to just 1 percent in the second quarter, with job growth averaging less than 100,000 per month for those 3 months. We also know that many Republican and Democratic State Governors are demanding immediate action to stop the automatic spending cuts, expressing concerns that sequestration would force their State economies back into a recession. So, while you have explained to us monetary policy that you are providing this leadership on and while you have given us great information today about what you feel would happen with this economy if we did not stimulate it, somewhat in the way that you are doing, I want to ask you, can you offer any insight or more insight into what the potential impact would be to our economy's recovery if the sequester were to take place as scheduled on March 1st? And can you elaborate on why you believe it is more important to focus, as you have said today, on deficit reduction over the long term rather than blunt austerity measures in the short term? I would like to hear more about this. Mr. Bernanke. Yes, ma'am. I cited in my testimony just the numbers from the Congressional Budget Office, which suggest that fiscal measures will reduce growth this year by 1.5 percentage points, which is very significant. If you look at the path of the deficit projected by the CBO, you see that for the next few years, progress has been made, and the debt-to-GDP ratio, in particular, doesn't look like it is going to be rising for the next few years. Where the problems arise which are the most serious are further out, when our aging society, rising health care costs, and so on, together with other costs, begin to bite. My suggestion for your consideration is to align the timing of your fiscal consolidation better with the problem. That is, to do somewhat less in the very near term when it will have the greatest impact on growth and jobs and where the Federal Reserve doesn't have any scope to offset it, and instead to focus on the longer term where the real problems, I think, still remain. Ms. Waters. So, you are not against cuts and you are not saying that we should not be involved in making cuts where we can make them. But what you are talking about is the level and the amount of the cuts that perhaps are being made which will slow down the growth in the economy. And you think that if we concentrate more on job development and stimulating the economy, that we should take a long-term approach to the cuts. Is that basically what you are saying? Mr. Bernanke. I am very much in favor of getting our fiscal house in order, but I think it is a long-run issue and I would be supportive of a less front-loaded set of measures. Ms. Waters. I think it is important to get that on the record because I have heard some discussion about your statement, even as it was made yesterday, and I think some people were confused and thought you were saying we shouldn't make any cuts. I think you are very clear about what you are proposing. And I thank you very much. And I yield back the balance of my time. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from California, Mr. Campbell, for 5 minutes. Mr. Campbell. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, unlike the ranking member, I have generally agreed with what you have said in the past, but now we diverge. So, it is funny how that happens. In the January 2013 FOMC meeting minutes which were just released, it reads, in part, ``A number of participants stated that an ongoing evaluation of the efficacy, costs, and risks of asset purchases might well lead the committee to taper or end its purchases before it judged that a substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market had occurred.'' If these voices are right and the unemployment does not drop significantly or below your target and inflation does not rise above your target, at what point do you decide to wind this down, call it quits, and try something else? Mr. Bernanke. As I said in my remarks, we have a cost- benefit framework, and we are going to be looking at both sides of that equation. We will be looking at benefits, trying to assess whether we are getting traction, whether the economy is benefiting from these policy moves, whether we are seeing a stronger economy, particularly in the labor market. On the cost side, we will be looking at inflation concerns and financial stability concerns that you mentioned in your opening remarks, Congressman. They are perhaps less important than the first two, but the remittances issue and perhaps some market functioning issues. We will be looking at the whole set of these concerns and trying to assess whether those costs are sufficient to induce a less aggressive policy or whether there are alternative measures--say, regulatory, supervisory, or other measures--that could more effectively or in a more precise way address those issues. So that will continue. We plan to have a continual discussion and review of both the costs and the benefits and try to make sure that we are taking the right steps, given those costs and benefits. Mr. Campbell. Is it safe to say that if the unemployment rate does not drop further as a result of these asset purchases, that is an indication that the benefits are declining? Mr. Bernanke. If we see no progress for an extended period, which I don't expect because we have already seen some progress, then I think we will want to discuss the efficacy side of the equation, is it working. My sense at this point--and it is very early--is that we are getting some traction in the housing market, which has shown some strength in the last few days, some of the data most recently. In automobiles and other durable goods, to some extent in investment, to some extent perhaps in commercial real estate, we have seen some signs of improvement. But we want to keep evaluating and seeing if, in fact, we are getting benefits from this policy. Mr. Campbell. There seems to be, towards that end, the benefits, a lot of evidence out there that the benefits of the low interest rate and quantitative easing are accruing primarily to the Federal Government, foreign governments, and large banks. Now, I think, clearly, those are not the entities that need to or that are doing the lion's share of hiring or need to do the majority of hiring. But do you agree with that view? And how do you rationalize the QE, given that view out there that is who is benefiting primarily from-- Mr. Bernanke. I completely disagree with that. This is very much focused at the average American citizen. Our estimates are that we have helped create many private sector jobs. Government jobs, of course, have been declining quite significantly. People are able to buy houses at very low mortgage rates or refinance at low mortgage rates. People are able to get car loans at low rates. Their house values have gone up so that they feel more financially secure. So in a lot of dimensions we have, I think, benefited Main Street, and that is certainly our objective. From the other sectors, we often get complaints. For example, banks have complained about the low interest rates squeezing their interest margin. I think the main benefits are those that are affecting the broader economy, and that is the broad group of Americans. Mr. Campbell. In the final 30 seconds, there is some concern that the agency MBS market is losing liquidity because I believe you are on pace to own, the Fed is, 20 percent of outstanding agency MBS and you are purchasing 40 percent of new issuance and that you are the market, there is no other market. Is that a concern? Mr. Bernanke. The market functioning, the Treasury and MBS market functioning, is something we do I wouldn't say every day but every hour, because we are heavily engaged in those markets, obviously. And, to this point, we don't see any significant problems with those markets. But if we do see problems, obviously we will react to that. But, to this point, we haven't seen anything significant. Mr. Campbell. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Missouri, Mr. Clay, for 5 minutes. Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, how would you describe the current condition of the U.S. housing market? Have we bounced back? And do you predict that we will witness significant employment gains if and when the housing market rebounds? Mr. Bernanke. As you know, the housing market took a tremendous blow: about 30 percent or more declines in prices; a massive decline in construction and sales. And that was a major factor, obviously, in the severity of the recession. As the chairman reminds me, it is difficult to make predictions, but the evidence thus far is that the housing market has hit the bottom and is recovering. We have seen rising prices over the last year or so. We have seen some significant increases in starts and sales. Foreclosures are still too high, but they are coming down. The number of people underwater in their mortgages is coming down. So we are still far from where we would like to be, but the evidence is that the housing market is strengthening and that low mortgage rates are one reason for that strengthening. And that should put people to work in several ways. It will put construction workers back to work, obviously, and people who work in factories that build appliances or other things that are related to housing. But, in addition, the increase in house prices and the increase in general economic activity should benefit other industries as well. Mr. Clay. Thank you for that response. Another area that seems to be ahead of pace of our economy is health care and the spiraling costs of health care. Do you foresee prices stabilizing there, or will it just continue to spiral out of control and hit consumers the hardest? Mr. Bernanke. This is a critically important issue because one of the main sources of our long-term budget problems is the fact that health care costs have gone up a lot faster than other costs over the last 40 years or so. Recently, in the last 4 or 5 years, health care costs have actually gone up somewhat more slowly. Part of that may be due to the recession and the fact that fewer people are able to afford or seek care. So I think it remains to be seen whether this relative decline in the pace of increase of health care costs is going to persist or not. If it does, it will be very good news, not only for Americans who are trying to afford health care, but also for the Federal budget. But I think there remains a lot to be done in the health care area to improve incentives, to improve quality, and to improve access. Mr. Clay. Thank you for that response. And I am sure we could have an entire hearing on just the cost of health care and the long-term and short-term goals for that area. Currently, the unemployment rate, according to the Labor Department, is 7.9 percent. What can the Federal Reserve and Congress do to put Americans back to work? I heard you say in your testimony that we should continue investing in job training and retraining. Any other suggestions? Mr. Bernanke. On the fiscal side, I mentioned, first, the notion of taking a longer-run perspective on addressing our fiscal sustainability issues to avoid some of the adverse effects in the near term of very sharp cuts and job losses. And the second point, as you noted, is that I think everyone would agree on both sides of the aisle that the money we do spend and the taxes we do collect should be done in the best way possible. We should be thinking about each program and is it achieving the objectives that we set for it and is it creating a better trained workforce, is it creating a more productive economy, is it creating a more fair and equitable and efficient Tax Code. Those are the kinds of issues that need to be addressed, as well as simply the total spending and revenue numbers. Mr. Clay. And, as you are aware, the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act required that Offices of Minority and Women Inclusion (OMWI) be established within agencies regulating financial institutions. What action has the Federal Reserve System taken to meet these requirements? Mr. Bernanke. We have followed everything required by the law. We have established an OMWI in the Fed and in each of the 12 Federal Reserve Banks. We are pursuing the supplier diversity and other requirements of the law. And we are working collectively, as we have been told to do, with the other agencies to develop some criteria for assessment of diversity practices in regulated institutions. Mr. Clay. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the vice chairman of the committee, the gentleman from California, Mr. Miller, for 5 minutes. Mr. Miller. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is good to have you here, Chairman Bernanke. I know you care about unemployment and inflation. You have expressed that in your statements over and over. And I know you care about the economy. But I am having some concerns with some of the regulations being proposed by the Fed right now. You did state that the housing market is recovering, and I agree with that, but it is very fragile, in my opinion. Some of the new housing regulations are very concerning. The QM was meant to protect consumers, but, as finalized, it really prevents creditworthy consumers from getting a mortgage, in my opinion. A recent study by CoreLogic says that 48 percent of the 2010 mortgage originations would be eligible under QM. And perhaps some of those shouldn't have been made, but that is a scary number. And I am concerned about the Federal Reserve's proposed rule on ability to repay as defined as qualified mortgage. Any loan that does not meet this requirement basically will not be made in the marketplace. And a recent study by CoreLogic says that is a huge problem. On QRM, it is meant to make sure that lenders have skin in the game. But, as drafted, the field will be so small that I am not sure there is going to be a field by the time you get through with it. We sent a letter to you--I think 208 Members signed-- complaining about the 20 percent down. If QRM is too narrow, I believe first-time home buyers will be driven out of the marketplace, which will cause another dip in the housing market. And Congress intended for mortgage insurance to be a qualifying factor in QRM. Could you please speak to that? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly. As you know, we couldn't finalize the QRM rules until the QM rules were completed because QRM can be no broader than QM. We have heard comments from Congress. We are considering them very carefully. I would say that the idea that QRM should be as broad or nearly as broad as QM is very much on the table. And we appreciate the concerns of Congress that these criteria should not so constraining as to prevent creditworthy borrowers from obtaining a mortgage. Mr. Miller. But you have lenders right now who are really keeping capital out of the marketplace because they don't know what is going to happen. At some point in time, we need to be very proactive in getting some form of a message out as to what the situation will be. Because it is really creating havoc in the industry, in my opinion. Do you agree with that? Mr. Bernanke. The uncertainty is certainly a problem, and it is one of the reasons why we haven't seen a resurgence of the private-label MBS market. But, again, now that QM is done, the agencies can work quickly to finalize the QRM rule. Mr. Miller. Okay. Another concern I have is bank capital standards are one issue, and insurance companies are completely different. The U.S. insurance companies hold about $5 trillion in assets today. And the Fed's proposed rule on capital standards based on Basel III, the rule is designed by bank regulators, which makes sense for banks, but they also apply to insurance companies. Insurance and banking are very different, as I know you agree. Strong capital standards are important, but they must be appropriate for the business model to which they apply. Will the Feds perform a qualitative impact study specific to insurance before you finalize the standard rules, like the QIS you do for banks? Mr. Bernanke. We are discussing the feasibility of such a study. And we recognize that there are important differences between banks and insurance companies. At the same time, of course, we have statutory constraints, the Collins Amendment, for example, that say that a certain amount of capital is necessary. But we have also heard from Congress about this insurance-banking distinction, and we are looking at it very seriously. We have been consulting, I should say, with the State insurance regulators, with the Federal Insurance Office, with the industry, and with a lot of other stakeholders to make sure we understand these issues. Mr. Miller. There is a tremendous amount of havoc in that industry today because of what they don't know. And, again, I think some action is pretty necessary in the immediate rather than in the long term on that, wouldn't you agree? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly. We want to get these rules out as quickly as possible. But on the other hand, as you point out, we need to make sure that they are appropriately set for the insurance business model, and that will take some time to study and understand. Mr. Miller. Okay. The last question you might not have time to answer, but you announced the QE3 last September. You said you would keep buying assets until there was substantial improvement in the labor market. I think you addressed it earlier. You said that mortgage-backed security purchases will boost economy by driving down long-term interest rates. But looking at the impact that QE3 has had on the mortgage market rates, we are at historically low levels right now. I am not seeing much change, but maybe that was the intent. But the Fed's balance sheet, like you said, had $3 trillion of holdings. Do you think that the mortgage interest rates are where they should be to meet the objectives of QE3, or do you think they need to be lower? Mr. Bernanke. I think they are low enough that they are providing a lot of assistance, a lot of help to homeowners. The low mortgage rates are a product not just of our latest program but of all the previous programs and our policies regarding short-term rates and the like. One of the paradoxes is that the best way to get interest rates up is to have low interest rates, because that promotes a stronger growing economy and that causes interest rates to rise. In some ways, the fact that interest rates have gone up a bit, and it happens on the real, not the inflation side, is actually indicative of a stronger economy, which, again, suggests that maybe this is having some benefit. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Mrs. Maloney, for 5 minutes. Mrs. Maloney. Thank you. Welcome, Chairman Bernanke. I believe this country owes you a debt of gratitude. Thank you for your leadership during one of the worst recessions in my lifetime. You took unprecedented measures which took our economy that was in a total freefall, and we are now on the road to recovery; however, I am deeply concerned about housing. As we all know, the housing market and the foreclosure crisis continues to be a major impediment to our economic growth. Some economists have estimated that housing and its related industries are 25 percent of our economy. So until we get this straight, we are not going to really fully and strongly recover, and that is why I want to spend my time this morning asking you about the Federal Reserve's role in the independent foreclosure review process. As you may know, I have written you and the OCC 3 letters over the past 2 months, and I would like permission if I may, Mr. Chairman, to place them in the record. Chairman Hensarling. Without objection, it is so ordered. Mrs. Maloney. I know the deadline that I gave your office was March 1st, but since we are only 48 hours away from that, I thought I would take this opportunity to get some clarity. First of all, how is it that in the past 18 months, over $1.5 billion has been given to independent consultants, but absolutely nothing has been given to the up to 4 million injured homeowners, some of whom have lost their homes unjustly during this 18-month review process? We have $9.3 billion in aid that is not helping any distressed homeowners. I have been told by parties involved in the process that there was an agreement between all the institutions that no aid would be given to help injured homeowners until all the institutions were ready and able to make payments. So first, who gave this order that no money would be paid to borrowers, to the people who were injured, while at the same time nearly $2 billion was generated in fees to private contractors? Mr. Bernanke. We agreed with you that plan was not working. As you know, the way it was set up was that the private consultants would evaluate the files and determine how much damages were warranted. They had not made all that much progress, frankly, and it was a very expensive cost per file evaluated, and we were on a track--and we take responsibility for this--where the money going to the consultants would be some multiple of the money going to the borrowers. So as you know, we have changed the process to a much quicker, more streamlined process, which is going to cut out the consultants and which will have checks going out to borrowers very, very shortly, within weeks. Mrs. Maloney. Don't you think that it would have been a better process if you had, and certainly more effective, to compensate borrowers whose harm was found and documented rather than wait for the entire process to be completed or to make this adjustment at midterm? We can put a person on the Moon. Why in the world can't we solve this? This whole foreclosure process is really dragging down the whole housing industry, because no one knows what to do. If you are going to send out checks soon, which I am glad to hear, how did you make the determination of who should receive these checks, and where are they going and what was the criteria? And what are you going to do to clean up this backlog and take this whole problem off and help the homeowners, which was the intention of the settlement to begin with, yet 2 years later no one has been helped? Mr. Bernanke. No. You are absolutely right. Mrs. Maloney. I can't tell you the stories I have heard of people who have lost their homes, and no one even knows who owns their home; it just sits there vacant. We have to get this straightened out. Can you just give me some timeframe and how we are going to fix this? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. We have agreements with most of the servicers, which will be made public shortly, because they are being incorporated into the enforcement orders under which they are operating. As you know, we have about a $9 billion agreement, all of which will be reflected either in cash payments or in mortgage relief to borrowers, none going to consultants. That is very much under way. My guess as to why the payments hadn't occurred until now is that it was just such a slow, ungainly process, but I will get you more information on that. On the criteria, we are going to have to use some shortcuts, because we don't have a full analysis. Mrs. Maloney. Do you think we should fall back-- Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. And the Chair now recognizes the chairman emeritus, the gentleman from Alabama, Mr. Bachus, for 5 minutes. Mr. Bachus. Thank you, Chairman Bernanke. Chairman Bernanke, I am going to ask you to reconsider the Fed's Proposed Rule 165 as it relates to foreign banking organizations which don't have a U.S. bank, but here in the United States only operate a broker-dealer. And let me give you four reasons. I don't want to engage you in a debate at this time, but first, to have that approach is different from any other regulatory regime that would apply to U.S. broker-dealers of our American companies. So you are using a different approach, but their broker-dealer doesn't have to be placed in that. Second, it is discriminatory, in my mind, because the securities broker-dealer of the foreign banking organization could have a higher capital standard because of the standard imposed on the intermediate bank holding company. We also have the longstanding principle of, I guess, national treatment where you don't have disparate treatment, and I think this violates that. Also, you have an expressed statutory provision that prohibits the Federal Reserve from overriding the capital requirements of a functionally regulated subsidiary of a bank holding company such as a broker-dealer subsidy whose capital requirements are established by the SEC. So to me, it would violate that. Now, I would also tell you to look at Section 165(b)(3) of Dodd-Frank, which says that in prescribing standards, the Fed should also take into account whether a foreign bank owns an insured bank as well as whether it has another primary regulator. So I would ask you, and I would think that you consulted with the SEC, that you consulted with the foreign regulators, but I just got back from Germany, and this was brought up on three different occasions by both government officials and European banks as to why are you treating us differently. I know you have extended the comment period of this rule to April 20th, but I would like to just exchange a series of letters and point out this in more detail. Mr. Bernanke. Thank you for calling that to my attention. Mr. Bachus. Thank you. And it is--there are over 100 foreign banks that are operating here that would be under--or could be under a different capital requirement than our local banks, and I think that could cause problems with our international regulators. And I am sure you have heard from some of them. Let me say to the membership, both Republicans and Democrats, and particularly those who have come here just in the past 5 years, Chairman Bernanke told us today exactly what he has told us for the last 5 years, and that is he has told us to focus on long-term structural changes to our mandatory spending programs, most of which are entitlements. And that ought to be our focus, and he said that today. He said that it will have a beneficial effect, a long-term beneficial effect, it will not retard economic recovery. Now, what have we done as opposed to what he has--and I have asked that same question to you for 5 years. You have always responded, focus on long-term structural changes, because of the demographics. What have we done? Last year, we had some success. This Congress doesn't get the benefit of--we had $2.5 trillion worth of cuts and revenue measures that reduced our debt for the next 10 years $2.5 trillion, and most people are saying we have about another trillion, $1.5 trillion to go. And I will say this. I know your hand is on the clock. This sequestration was a bipartisan mistake by Members of both parties. We were told it wouldn't go into effect. That is a gamble we will lose on March 1st. What we need to do is substitute these short-term changes for maybe going up on the retirement age 2 months or some means testing. This is not rocket science. And I say to the President and to this Congress, quit fiddling around, get to work, and let us come up with $85 trillion worth of long-term structural changes. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from New York, Ms. Velazquez, for 5 minutes. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, will you please help me out? Did you state in your testimony that we need to make structural changes to entitlement programs or did you say that front-loaded spending cuts required by the sequestration with policies that reduce the Federal deficit more gradually in the near term, but more substantially in the longer run? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Congresswoman, I said that you need to be looking at the long run-- Ms. Velazquez. Okay. Mr. Bernanke. --which is where the problems are most serious. Ms. Velazquez. Mr. Chairman, as it has been stated, the housing sector has continued to see improvement with increased construction activity and higher home prices. As you know, the rate of economic recovery relies heavily on a robust housing market. And I am interested in hearing from you what will be the impact or the effect to the economy if Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the FHA were scaled back or abolished, as some policymakers have proposed? Mr. Bernanke. Currently, Fannie, Freddie, and FHA are pretty much the whole mortgage market. Other than portfolio lending by banks, there is not much in the way of alternative securitization. So simply shutting them down without doing anything else would no doubt restrict credit quite considerably, but I think we all agree-- Ms. Velazquez. And it would have an impact on job creation? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. I think we all agree that over the longer run, we need to come to a more acceptable set of institutions, but right now, of course, they are providing most of the support for the mortgage market. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you. Mr. Chairman, past iterations of the Basel allowed exemptions for community banks from the complex capital rules imposed on large multinational banks. Was that approach considered for this round of Basel? Mr. Bernanke. I am not sure I quite understood. The-- Ms. Velazquez. In Basel I and Basel II, small banks, community banks were exempted from those rules. Now in Basel III, they were not. They were not the ones that created the economic crisis. Mr. Bernanke. Of course. The community banks have always been subject to capital rules, of course. They are exempt from many, many of the more complex rules which apply to large internationally active banks, and that will continue to be the case. And I am sure you are alluding to concerns that small banks have raised about-- Ms. Velazquez. Right. Mr. Bernanke. --the recent proposed rule. We have heard that from Members on both sides of the aisle as well as from the industry and other stakeholders, and we are looking at that very carefully. Ms. Velazquez. I am concerned about that, because when we look at the survey of loan officers, it still shows that access to capital for small businesses continues to hinder economic growth, and community banks are the one that lend to small businesses. I am concerned to know whether or not someone was advocating for community banks when it comes to imposing regulations on Basel III. Mr. Bernanke. We are looking carefully both at community banks and at small business lending, and we recognize the importance of those two institutions. Ms. Velazquez. Thank you. Mr. Campbell [presiding]. Does the gentlelady yield back her time? Ms. Velazquez. I do. Mr. Campbell. The gentlelady yields back her time. Now, the chairwoman of the Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit Subcommittee, the gentlelady from West Virginia, Mrs. Capito, is recognized for 5 minutes. Mrs. Capito. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being with us today. I would like to add my voice of concern to the previous questioner, Ms. Velazquez, on the issue of the Basel III and the effect it is having on and could have on our community banks. We had a hearing several months ago, and it was pretty unanimous in the hearing from all voices that there is a serious concern on what impact this could have on lending for small businesses and the ability really for community banks to survive and flourish. I know you have already answered that question, so I appreciate the fact that you are keeping that in mind as we move forward on this regulatory issue. You talked about the sequester and talked about how you would prefer it to go at a more gradual pace rather than the more dramatic pace that it appears that it could be going at this point, because of the influence of jobs. I have a great idea. I live in an energy State. If we would unleash the power of this country to really have a full and flourishing energy economy, both including in my State, coal and natural gas, but Keystone Pipeline and others, we would have thousands of people, more people working, we would have energy independence, we could have availability of natural gas as a transportation fuel. It fuels our chemical industry and our power generation. So I would like, from your perspective, and I am very frustrated by the regulatory issues and, I think the inability of the Administration to move forward in full-out energy independent policies that I think could create many, many jobs. Where do you see energy as a part of the whole national economy, energy independence and the job effects that an energy economy can bring? Mr. Bernanke. Energy has been one of the bright spots in our economy in the last couple of years. We have seen tremendous increases of production of natural gas, increasing oil production. There is talk of coming close to energy independence over the next few years. That has created a lot of jobs and has been a positive factor in many parts of our country. Of course, there are always environmental issues which arise, and I am frankly not qualified-- Mrs. Capito. Right. Mr. Bernanke. --to give you a sense of how those balance out against each other. I hope that solutions can be found which will preserve the environment and also allow for the development of our resources, because as you say, it creates jobs and reduces our vulnerability to foreign energy sources. Mrs. Capito. You mentioned gas prices as a reason that is hurting our economy in general, and certainly all of our constituents are feeling this very much. I think energy economy, there again, could answer in a small way and maybe a large way the issue of gasoline as we move towards energy independence. So, I would like to hear you talk about the energy economy more as part of our broader economy, because I think you said it is a bright spot; let's feature it as a way for us to pull ourselves out of a slower recovery. So I would encourage you to do that. My other question is on seniors. Many of us are in that sandwich generation trying to help our parents, and our parents are doing a pretty good job trying to help themselves, but they are relying on their good planning and investments, if they have been lucky enough to invest. The dividend and interest availabilities to them are crushing our seniors as they see their health care costs go up. And some of the policies that you have put forward, I think, and that the Fed has caused concern for those of us who are concerned about seniors who don't have the ability to get another job--that is played out for them. What can I tell my seniors back home that is going to give them some optimism that they are going to be able to rely on that good planning that they had to carry them through to their senior years? Mr. Bernanke. I would say first that savers have many hats. They may own fixed-income instruments like bonds, but they also may own stocks or a house or a business. All of those other assets benefit when the economy strengthens. Mrs. Capito. Right. Mr. Bernanke. And those values have gone up. The stock market has roughly doubled, as you know, in the past 2 years. So from an investment perspective, there are alternatives. I think more importantly, though, you are not going to get strong returns in an economy that is fundamentally weak. The best way to get sustainable high returns to savers is to get the economy back to running on all cylinders. And it is somewhat paradoxical, but in some ways the best way to get interest rates up is not to raise them too quickly, because by keeping rates low now, we can help the economy get stronger, we can create more jobs, we can create more momentum in the economy. That is the way to get a sustainable higher set of interest rates. It is very striking that if you look at every other industrial country around the world, interest rates are about exactly where they are here, and that says something about the fundamentals, which are very weak in most of these industrial countries. And until we can get greater forward momentum, we are not going to be able to see sustainable higher returns. Mrs. Capito. All right. Thank you very much. Mr. Campbell. The gentlelady's time has expired. The gentleman from California, Mr. Sherman, is recognized for 5 minutes. Mr. Sherman. Chairman Bernanke, I want to thank you for the wisdom to recognize that our country needs an expansionary monetary policy, the fortitude to stick with it when apparently you have some critics, and the creativity to go beyond your traditional tools in carrying out that policy. I listened carefully to my California Republican colleagues. I want to associate myself with Mr. Miller in his comments about a QRM definition that isn't too far from the QM definition. I heard Mr. Campbell criticize the Fed because he hears people saying that you shouldn't fight the Fed and it is hard to price risk. I am pretty old. I have seen your predecessors carry out just about every kind of Fed policy I can imagine. Everybody is always muttering, don't fight the Fed. And the only time they ever say it is easy to price risk is when they are wrong. So the mutterings that the gentleman from California hears are fully consistent with not only your monetary policy, but every other monetary policy you could imagine. And Ms. Velazquez points out how important Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are, and FHA. We heard testimony here from Moody's Analytics that if FHA hadn't been there, we would have seen another 25 percent decline in home prices. In my view, if that had happened, America would look somewhere between Greece and Thunderdome. So it is fortunate that we have those institutions. We have a lot of capital on the sidelines, as the gentleman from California pointed out. Investment needs funds, but it also needs people willing to take a risk. Some criticize that as reaching for yield, but if everybody is only willing to invest in investments where the appropriate yield is 2 or 3 percent, we are not going to have any small business lending. I have never seen a small business with a 98 percent chance of success. We have banks out there, they have a lot of capital, they face a lot of pressure to invest at 2 and 3 and 4 percent. I am told by bankers that if they invest in something that has, say, an 8 percent likelihood of default, they don't face an 8 percent reserve or a 10 percent reserve or a 12 percent reserve, they get 100 percent charge to capital. What can the Fed do so that loans that are a bit--they are not just the 2 or 3 percent loans, are valued conservatively and the portfolio is valued conservatively, but not with a penalty valuation? Mr. Bernanke. I would like to continue that discussion with you. The reserving practices are mostly tied to actual problems with loans, not with loans that are made that may be risky, ex ante. And, in fact, one of the issues that has been an issue for a while is can banks put aside reserves against general risk of credit loss as opposed to losses in specific loans. So we have generally been supportive actually of banks doing more reserving so they would have some reserves available against losses not yet seen or understood, but I think maybe we need to have a further conversation about this. Mr. Sherman. I look forward to that. Timing is everything in a lot of fields. This is a pretty ideological city right now, and an ideologue either believes that it is always the right time to cut taxes, always the right time to cut spending, or always the right time to increase spending, or always the right time to increase taxes, or always the right time to do whatever their ideology requires. In your opening statement, you point out that the Fed is adopting a different approach. You actually have different policies for different business conditions and your line is 6\1/2\ percent unemployment, along with some other factors. The national debt is a growing cancer, but this is an economy that suffered a heart attack in 2008. And you don't administer chemotherapy while a patient is still in the cardiac ICU. Would the markets have confidence in Congress, and it is hard to think of whether they would ever have confidence in Congress, if we have statutory provisions which, like your policies, had a trigger and moved toward a more contractionary fiscal policy with, say, a 6\1/2\ percent unemployment rate? Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired, and the Chairman can answer the question in writing. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New Jersey, Mr. Garrett, for 5 minutes. Mr. Garrett. I thank the chairman and I thank Chairman Bernanke. Let me just try to run through in 5 minutes three areas, what you talked about on remittances, what you talked about as far as some of the positive results, and if we have time, some of the effects of the somewhat current loose monetary policy on an international state. So on remittances, I think you already said that the remittances are here, but they are potentially to go down in the future. If you look at the consolidated balance sheet of the Federal Reserve, we have capital of less than $55 billion, and assets of more than $3 trillion, so that means that all you need is about a 1 quarter of 1 percent increase in the interest rates, and you basically wipe out what you basically have right now, which is a 55 to 1 ratio, and you wipe that out. So what is your prediction actually on that going forward with regard to interest rates wiping that ratio out and the effect on remittances to Congress? Can you be more specific on the numbers? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly. So currently, as I have said, we have in the last 4 years, remitted $290 billion, we currently have more than $200 billion of unrealized capital gains on our balance sheet. The capital issue is irrelevant. We have additional funding behind the capital. We have $3 trillion of liabilities which are not callable liabilities, like cash, for example. Mr. Garrett. I guess I would just ask you if you could follow up on detail on that, because that is not the way I understand it, but I would ask you to put that in writing. Mr. Bernanke. The main reality here is that if interest rates rise very quickly, then there may be a period where we don't pay any remittances at all to the Treasury. That is the actual outcome. That is important. Under most, and I would say virtually all scenarios, we will be sending remittances to the Treasury substantially higher than the norms established before the crisis. Mr. Garrett. Since my time is limited, what we are looking at here is around $90 billion in remittances if--you said we could actually see that almost go down to eliminate it. Right now, we are trying to do a sequester at $85 billion. So it sort of puts us in perspective as to what the effect could be as far as your policies there. With regard to the positive indications that you have indicated, you said the stock market and the housing market have gone up because of your monetary policy, but previously you said that the Fed's monetary policy actions earlier this decade, in 2003-2005, did not contribute to the housing bubble in the United States. So which is it? Is monetary policy by the Fed not a cause of inflationary prices of housing, as you have said in the past, or is it a cause of inflating prices of housing? Can you have it both ways? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Garrett. You can? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, we can have it both ways, because they are different phenomena. The mortgage rate is a quantitative thing. House prices are going up a reasonable amount, given the strengthening of the housing market, given the strengthening of the economy, given where mortgage rates are. But mortgage rates in the early part of this last decade were around 6 percent. That can't explain why house prices rose as much as they did. Maybe it was a small contribution, but it certainly can't explain the big run-up and then decline. Mr. Garrett. But now it is. So the other area you indicated why we should say your policies are working in a cost-benefit analysis is the stock market. I am sure you are familiar with Milton Friedman's work that says that people only really consume off of their permanent income, which basically means that you don't consume increased consumption because your stocks have gone up in the marketplace. And to that point, I know Mrs. Capito asked the question as to what seniors should do in this situation, and you said, take it out of some fixed assets and put it into the stock market. Heaven forbid that my 90-year-old mother would take her money out of fixed markets and put it in the stock market. I think that is probably the worst advice that is out there. And when you consider that a 1 percent increase in the stock market only has infinitesimal, maybe a 100 percent increase in GDP, I really don't understand: first, how you can give that advice; or second, how you can suggest that an increase in the stock market is a positive indicator of your work in a cost-benefit analysis to the rest of the economy. Mr. Bernanke. I was not giving financial advice. I apologize if I gave that impression. I was just saying-- Mr. Garrett. But she was asking you-- Mr. Bernanke. --that generally-- Mr. Garrett. She was asking you the question, what should you be doing to benefit the seniors, what should we say to the seniors. And your comments were-- Mr. Bernanke. What I was saying was that the economy will get stronger because of good policies and that in turn will cause rates to rise in a sustainable way. If we were to raise rates prematurely, we would kill the recovery and rates would come down and we would have a long-term situation with very low rates. Mr. Garrett. But wouldn't you have provided for the certainty in the marketplace so you could have more price transparency? Earlier, you said that some risk-taking in the market is appropriate. That was one of your opening comments. Sure, risk-taking is appropriate, but it is appropriate when there is actual price discovery. When you have a market that is distorted, as it is right now by the Fed's monetary policy, you really don't have true price discovery. And so when you do risk-taking now, it is based upon not really knowing what the appropriate value is of land prices, equity markets prices, so risk-taking now is worse than risk-taking is when the Fed's actions do not distort the marketplace. If you would say--thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New York, Mr. Meeks, for 5 minutes. Mr. Meeks. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, more of us thank you for all of your work and what you do with reference to our great country. In your opening statement, you talked a lot and you indicated about jobs, and I think that is the going subject matter. Everybody is concerned about jobs on both sides of the aisle, and the creation of jobs, yet we have had 35 straight months of private sector job growth, but we are continuing to have, as you said, high, and stubbornly high, unemployment rates. And as I look at it, with that steady growth, we have shed over 600,000 public sector jobs since the beginning of the financial crisis in late 2008. In fact, The Wall Street Journal estimated last year that the unemployment rate would be at least one full percentage point lower if we still had those jobs, those 600,000 jobs. So my question to you is, what strains have these massive public sector layoffs put on your ability to stabilize the employment sector, and what do you think we need to do in regards to that to replace those jobs? Mr. Bernanke. Let me first say that I understand why States and localities in particular laid off a lot of workers, because their tax revenues went down, they had to balance their budgets, and that was the only option they had, but it is true that State and local governments, their retrenchment during the recovery and their layoffs were a headwind for the broader economic recovery. In fact, the fiscal retrenchment at the State and local level in this recovery has been much more severe than in virtually any other recovery. So the good news, I guess, and one of the reasons why I think we may have a somewhat stronger economy going forward is that State and local governments seem now to have stabilized their budgets, and as a result we don't expect to see those ongoing layoffs to the extent that we have seen them in the past. But, yes, it is true that the contraction of State and local government budgets, together with more recent cuts in the Federal budget, has resulted in job loss certainly in those sectors and in the economy more broadly. Mr. Meeks. And sequestration as we see it right now on a Federal level could exacerbate that with-- Mr. Bernanke. I have cited the Congressional Budget Office, which I think has reasonable estimates, yes. Mr. Meeks. Let me also go to a question, because you have been asked about banks and banks lending, and Alan Blinder had an op ed in The Wall Street Journal last year, if I recall, pointing out that in an effort to spur lending by banks, central banks in Europe are cutting their interest, cutting the interest they pay on excess reserves to zero. In fact, the Danish cut it to a negative 0.2 percent, meaning banks would have to pay the central bank to keep reserves with them. Now, this seems to me to be a powerful incentive to either lend or put money to work in the markets. So my question is, do you believe that this policy, if implemented here, would it benefit the U.S. economy? And if not, why not? Mr. Bernanke. Banks are currently being paid on their reserves 25 basis points, one-fourth of 1 percent. They are actually receiving less than that on net, because they also have to pay FDIC premiums on the deposits that they hold on the other side of their balance sheet, so they are receiving just a few basis point on their reserves. If we cut the interest on reserves, say, to zero or slightly negative, which is possible, it would have a very, very small effect in the right direction, but a very, very small effect on the incentives of banks to make loans. Basically, they are not finding as many loans as they would like to make when they are earning 8 basis points on their reserves. Would it help to get it down to zero? It is in the right direction, as I said, but one of the reasons that we have hesitated to do that is because it would also lower returns throughout the money markets in our economy and would create some problems in terms of the functioning of money markets, the Federal funds market, and other short-term cash markets. So it is not clear that the benefits in terms of more stimulus outweigh the costs in terms of market functioning. That being said, it has always been something that we have kept on the table and talked about periodically. Mr. Meeks. So it is something that is still on the table and you are still talking about? Because I like movement in the right direction. Mr. Bernanke. It is not a powerful tool, though, in any sense. Mr. Meeks. I have 10 seconds left, I don't think I am going to get my next question in, but the--because my next question was basically what you were told--told Senator-- Chairman Hensarling. No, no. The gentleman cannot get his next question in. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Neugebauer, for 5 minutes. Mr. Neugebauer. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, Chairman Bernanke, thank you for being here this morning. Mr. Chairman, I want to walk through the proposed exit strategy that I think was put forward in June of 2011 and see if you foresee taking any different steps. I believe in that exit strategy you said we would begin to cease reinvesting payments of principal on security holdings, I guess as they matured. The second part of that was raising the Fed funds rate while adjusting the interest rate on excess reserves and levels of reserves in the banking system to kind of bring those funds towards a targeted rate. And then I think the third part of that was selling off some of the Fed securities after the first increase in the target for the Federal funds rate. So according, though, to the most recent FOMC minutes released, a number of participants discussed the possibility of providing monetary accommodation by holding securities for a longer period of time than what was originally envisioned by the committee's exit principles, either to supplement or to replace other asset purchases. This kind of suggests a deviation from the course put forward in 2011, and I would suspect there may be other changes that are being discussed from the June 20th exit strategy as well. So you have laid out this exit strategy, and now based on these subsequent conversations and discussions that are going on, how confident should investors and the business community be that this exit strategy will be the same 6 months from now or 3 years from now? And given the huge size of your balance sheet and the potential uncertainty that changes in this exit strategy could cause, are you concerned that we are creating some additional uncertainty in an already uncertain economy? Mr. Bernanke. No, I don't think so. We haven't done a new review of the exit strategy yet. I think we will have to do that some time soon. I am pretty confident the basic outline that you just described would still be in force. The one thing we could do differently, as you pointed out, is hold some of the securities a little longer. We could even let them just run off. I just want to be clear that even if we don't sell any securities, it doesn't mean that our balance sheet is going to be large for many years. It just would be maybe an extra year. That is all it would take to get back down to a more normal size. So that is one issue, how long to hold the securities and whether to use that as a substitute, an alternative to asset purchases. I think that is something worth discussing, but I don't see any radical shift in the way this is going to happen. And, again, as I said earlier, we are quite comfortable that we can exit in a way that is both smooth and in which we provide lots of information to markets in advance so they will know what is coming and be able to anticipate it. Mr. Neugebauer. I thought it was kind of interesting when you said that we need to take a slower approach to deficit reduction and that the economy couldn't withstand a major reduction in government spending. Don't you find it a little disconcerting that we have let the government become so much of the economy that cutting our deficit so that we don't mortgage the future of our children and grandchildren should be even a consideration in deficit reduction? Mr. Bernanke. Government is an important part of every advanced economy now. And I am not by any means saying that we should not deal with the deficit problem. I am just saying we should take a longer-term perspective. Mr. Neugebauer. When people talk about fiscal policy and monetary policy, you always say, I am in charge of monetary policy, not fiscal policy, but Mr. Chairman, I almost find the Fed to be a deficit enabler in the environment that we are in right now. And the reason I would say that is the fact that last year, I think you transferred about $90 billion back to the Treasury. So basically, whatever securities that they yield, you buy down their yield to almost zero. You have put $90 billion additional money in the hands of the government, yet we still ran a $1.2 trillion deficit. So we are almost enabling the government to continue to spend, because we are allowing them to have this borrowing habit at a very cheap price because of the actions that you are taking at the Fed to buy those yields down. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has-- Mr. Neugebauer. You can follow up and answer in writing. Mr. Bernanke. Okay. I will follow up. Chairman Hensarling. If you can follow up in writing, please. The gentleman from Massachusetts, Mr. Capuano, is recognized for 5 minutes. Mr. Capuano. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here again. Mr. Chairman, I have read most of the 57-page report and I have read your 9 pages, and honestly every time any Fed Chairman has ever come before here, it is like I get a headache before, during, and afterwards. I love you dearly, but trying to parse all these things that everybody is saying is very difficult for average people, including me. And I guess I want to read one sentence from your testimony to make sure that I understand it correctly. This is from your testimony: ``To address both the near and long-term issues, the Congress and the Administration should consider replacing the sharp front-loaded spending cuts required by the sequestration with policies that reduce the Federal deficit more gradually in the near term, but more substantially in the longer run.'' I think I read this correctly, but would it be fair for me to paraphrase this to average people that the Chairman of the Federal Reserve thinks that sequestration is stupid? Mr. Bernanke. I wish you wouldn't do that. What I am saying-- Mr. Capuano. But would it be fair? Mr. Bernanke. What I am saying is that by a more gradual approach but with more cuts in the longer term achieves both objectives, not slowing the recovery by too much, but on the other hand addressing these long-term issues that Congressman-- Mr. Capuano. Like I said, I am getting a headache again. From what I just heard, you said, again to paraphrase, not to quote, that you think sequestration is stupid. And I agree with you. Don't worry. It is okay. Sequestration is going to get its fair share of attention today and this week and next week, but I want to focus on something that is a little bit more closely related to directly what the Fed does, and that is the too-big- to-fail. I was reading your testimony from yesterday, and the written testimony, and again I want to read your words as reported relative to too-big-to-fail on the subsidy, relative to the too-big-to-fail thing. And you say, the subsidy is coming because of market expectations that the government would bail out these firms if they failed, period. Those expectations are incorrect. That is a quote from you. Is that a fair-- Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Capuano. Okay. So am I reading this correctly that you believe that at least through legislative purposes, that too- big-to-fail is just nonexistent anymore, not through the market, but through the law? Mr. Bernanke. We don't have--the tools that were used in 2008 are gone now. What we have instead is the Orderly Liquidation Authority, which among other things would wipe out all the shareholders of the company being liquidated. Now, if we had a systemically large important firm fail tomorrow, it still could be very damaging to our economy. And we are working-- Mr. Capuano. I understand. We could do something-- Mr. Bernanke. --working in that direction. Mr. Capuano. --but the law currently as drafted, after Dodd-Frank and after all of the things we have been through, today we do not have the tools that we used to implement too- big-to-fail as it was in 2008. Mr. Bernanke. The tools that the Federal Reserve used are no longer available to us. Mr. Capuano. I am glad to hear that. And I also agree with you that regardless of what the law says, some people in the marketplace, especially some of my friends on the other side of the aisle, like to believe that it is still in existence. And I accept that, not as a legal point, but as a fact of reality. Some people think that the Moon is made of cheese, and that is fine. To them, that is real. So for some people, too-big-to- fail is still there, though there is no scientific or legal proof that it is. I guess what I am asking is, what do you suggest that we do to address that misconception of the market and the misconception of some of my own colleagues that too-big-to-fail is still here? Because I think we all agree that we don't want it to be here, it is not here. How do we address that misconception to make it a reality? Mr. Bernanke. Dodd-Frank as a strategy involves making big institutions internalize, take account of their systemic costs by tougher regulation, higher capital charges, and so on, the Orderly Liquidation Authority and strengthening the entire system. So there are steps that we are taking that are moving in that direction. I think the markets will come to see that these steps are effective. Of course, we can communicate it, we can say it, but-- Mr. Capuano. But we have been saying it for years now, and some people refuse to believe it. Do you accept the general-- and, again, not for the dollar, but there have been some studies that put the subsidy that--the alleged subsidy that is there for the too-big-to-fail that doesn't exist anyway, but that market perception of a subsidy-- Mr. Bernanke. Yes. No. There still is some--I am sure there is still some-- Mr. Capuano. And I accept that. Mr. Bernanke. --market perception. It is declining, but we need to be working in the direction of eliminating it entirely. Mr. Capuano. And do you think that subsidy can be quantified in a reasonable way? Mr. Bernanke. With lots of assumptions and so on, you can compare what large banks pay in the market to what small banks pay, and that gives you some sense-- Mr. Capuano. Be prepared to get a request from me later on to try to do that quantification. Mr. Bernanke. Senator Warren cited some studies to me yesterday, so maybe-- Mr. Capuano. Yes, but that is not your study. I want yours. Thank you. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. McHenry, for 5 minutes. Mr. McHenry. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And, Chairman Bernanke, thank you for your service to our government, and to our people. To follow up on my colleague from Texas' question about Fed policy masking the true cost of our fiscal profligacy, now, the question is, would the Fed buying 48 percent of U.S. debt for Fiscal Year 2013 and with a zero or negative real interest rate, isn't the Fed the great enabler of our debt? I understand Congress and the President make fiscal policy, but isn't the Fed's policy in essence masking the true cost of our debt? Mr. Bernanke. If I can make three points. The first is that as a share of all the debt outstanding, the Fed's ownership is actually lower today than it was before the crisis. We own about 15, 16 percent of all the debt outstanding. So those interest rates you see on the debt comes from actual market trading between private sector individuals. The second point is that, as I have emphasized today, there is a very long-term problem here. What is going to matter is the interest rate not today, but the interest rate 5 years from now, 10 years from now, 15 years from now. Congress, I hope, has the foresight to see that interest rates will not be this low forever and, therefore, they should take that into account. And then, finally, I ask, what is the alternative? If we raised interest rates substantially just to make it harder for the Congress to borrow, if at the same time we do damage to the economy and lower revenues and make the deficit even worse, I don't see how that is really helpful to our fiscal situation. So my hope is that Congress will recognize that interest rates will rise over time as our economy recovers and that this is a long-term proposition and they should take that into account in their decisions. Mr. McHenry. So in the short run, yes? Mr. Bernanke. No. And, again, we only have about 15, 17 percent of the total debt outstanding. It is not the case that we are buying, all the debt being-- Mr. McHenry. No, no. Just 48 percent this fiscal year. Mr. Bernanke. Of the new debt-- Mr. McHenry. Yes. Mr. Bernanke. --but not on average. Again, 85 percent of it is circulating in private hands. Mr. McHenry. Okay. Now, to go to a separate point, Bloomberg reported that at your recent meeting of the Treasury Borrowing Advisory Committee, which is a group of senior bankers and investors, they received a presentation that warned that the central bank's policies, and I am quoting from Bloomberg News, may be inflating bubbles and speculative grade bonds and other asset classes. Is this an acceptable side effect of the Fed's expansionary policies? Mr. Bernanke. As I have mentioned, it is a cost of these policies and it is one that we take very seriously. We look at these possible mispricings and we ask ourselves, are they in fact mispricings, how large are they? And if they are mispricings, what is the vulnerability? For example, if an asset is mispriced, is it being purchased using a lot of leverage? Who is owning it? Would its change in its price severely endanger our financial institutions? Those kinds of things. So we are examining this with a great of a deal of care. And again, I ask, what is the alternative? Interest rates are low for a good reason, but if in fact we have come to the conclusion that the cost of these mispricings are sufficient, then obviously we have to take that into account. Mr. McHenry. So to this point about inflation, many of us have this concern about how you are going to unwind this unprecedented portfolio that you preside over, or how your successor will unwind this, or your successor's successor. And the concern that we have is that you only can see inflation with hindsight. And the question I have for you concerns the record of the 1970s: in 1973 expected inflation was 3.75 percent, that was the market expectation, the Fed said 3.9 percent, the actual was 6.2 percent; in 1974 expected inflation was 6.7 percent, the Fed said 8 percent, yet the actual inflation was 11 percent; in 1979 expected inflation was 8.3 percent, the Fed said 7.75 percent, the actual was 11.3 percent. And in 1980, expected inflation was predicted at 11 percent, the Fed said 7.5 percent, yet the actual was 13\1/2\ percent. The Fed has consistently gotten it wrong. Are your tools better now to see inflation than they were then when we had this great period of inflation? Mr. Bernanke. Our tools are better, but the environment is much better, because we now have 25 years of success in keeping inflation low and stable, and not just in the United States but around the world. Inflation expectations are very well-anchored and wages are growing very slowly. Chairman Hensarling. The tme of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Georgia, Mr. Scott, for 5 minutes. Mr. Scott. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Over here, Chairman Bernanke. How are you? It is good to see you again. First, I want to commend you for the very courageous and bold work that you have done in the aggressive quantitative easing in which you have moved very forthrightly to strengthen our economy with the purchasing of Treasury and GSA securities, and I want to commend you for that. But, Chairman, I have always known you to be a straight shooter. I have great respect for you. We are on the eve of a very, very dramatic moment in American history dealing with this sequestration. And the President of the United States has said it is a terrible thing to do. The Democrats have said it is a terrible thing to do. We are fighting to avoid it. The Secretary of Defense has come before us and said it is threatening our national security, we better not do it. We have had our Transportation Secretary, we have had Homeland Security Secretaries, but yet we have Republicans who are saying, and who are determined to move ahead and say, let's do it. I want you to tell us today, who is right here? Who is telling the truth here? Is sequestration something that we should not do, as Democrats feel, or is it something we should do, as Republicans feel? What is in the best interest of America? Mr. Bernanke. Congressman, you are asking me to make decisions which are not mine to make. Those are congressional decisions. Congress has to make those choices. What I am advising is a more gradual approach. I am not saying that we should ignore the deficit. I am not saying we shouldn't deal with long-term fiscal issues, but I think from the perspective of our recovery, a more gradual approach would be constructive. Mr. Scott. When you say ``gradual,'' what specifically would gradual mean? Give us an example. Mr. Bernanke. It works all in the same direction. The more gradual this is, as long as there are offsetting changes in the further horizon, the less the immediate impact will be on jobs and growth in this recovery in 2013. Mr. Scott. And do you agree that gradual approach should contain both spending cuts and additional revenue? Mr. Bernanke. That, again, comes back to what Congress is responsible for. I am not going to comment on that. Mr. Scott. I am very, very concerned about this, because my home State of Georgia will suffer tremendously on this. I represent a district that has Lockheed Martin, for example, which has already come under tremendous job loss pressure. We are looking at over 60,000 jobs immediately. We are looking-- and those jobs are teachers being laid off, firefighters being laid off, critical, critical manpower that is needed. Let me ask you: Friday comes, we go over the cliff with sequestration. What should we do next? Should we then try to consistently move to put something in place? How would you advise us to do that, and what would that step entail? Mr. Bernanke. Again, the specifics are up to you, but what I would suggest would be replacing the sequester with something that is smaller, takes hold more slowly, but is compensated for by changes further out in the horizon. Mr. Scott. And do you see a complicating factor with the approaching deadline of the March CR? If, for example, we are unable to reach an agreement in 4 months, what impact would we have with sequestration moving rapidly through the system, massive job layoffs, all of the predictions coming true that we feel and then with our failure to reach agreement on the CR at the end of March? Mr. Bernanke. The CR, I guess, would continue government services. I think there is some cost to the economy of these repeated, I don't want to say crises, but these repeated episodes where Congress is unable to come to some agreement, and therefore some automatic thing kicks in. I think that is on the whole not a good thing for confidence. And, again, as I said yesterday, I realize that finding bipartisan agreement is very difficult, but I hope that you will work together to try to develop a less bumpy fiscal path in the near term. Mr. Scott. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Campbell. We now turn to the other gentleman from Georgia, Mr. Westmoreland. He is recognized for 5 minutes. Mr. Westmoreland. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, the Federal Reserve at this point is buying $85 billion worth of mortgage-backed securities a month, is that correct? Mr. Bernanke. No, sir, it is 40 of mortgage backed and 45 of treasuries. Mr. Westmoreland. Okay, but a total of 85. Mr. Bernanke. Yes, sir. Mr. Westmoreland. Because all the talk we have had about the sequester being $85 billion over a year for the whole Federal Government, I think when you realize what we are doing with these mortgage-backed securities, it kind of puts it in a perspective that do we really need to be buying that kind of securities every month? Mr. Bernanke. This doesn't involve any new spending or revenue. Mr. Westmoreland. I understand. Just printing money, right? Mr. Bernanke. It is acquiring securities in order to reduce interest rates and ease financial conditions in the economy. Mr. Westmoreland. Let me ask you, I know that you make the decisions as far as what you think it will take, and I guess the Board of Governors, for what you think it will take to run the Federal Reserve, and as my colleague from Georgia mentioned, we represent a State that has had more bank failures than I think any other. I know my congressional district has more than any other congressional district. What is the Federal Reserve doing to let these banks which are community banks and they know their communities and they know their borrowers, what is the Federal Reserve doing to let them have more latitude in making some of the decisions about the banking needs of the community and how they can best solve that? Because what we basically hear is that the regulators, the FDIC, OCC, Federal Reserve, State regulators, are not really letting them answer the needs of the community. Mr. Bernanke. We are very interested in the success of small community banks. We agree that they play a very important role in communities. We have a whole list of things, I won't have time, but we have a Community Bank Council that comes and meets with the Board and gives their views. We have a special subcommittee of our Supervision Committee that is particularly focused on how rules can be made appropriate for smaller banks. We train our examiners to take into account the size of banks and their particular business models. We have all kinds of outreach. We are looking at our rules with the understanding that community banks can't manage the same level of regulatory burden that large banks can handle. So we are very committed to helping small community banks succeed in this environment. You have my assurance that is something we pay a lot of attention to. Mr. Westmoreland. I know that as I meet with my community bankers, and we have a little advisory board for the bank, and they are very concerned about Basel III, they are very concerned about the writedowns that they are having to do immediately rather than having some time period to do it. And I understand that you have all these things evidently in place to try to help the community banks. I just haven't seen it. Nobody, none of my community bankers have said, hey, the Federal Reserve or the FDIC or anybody else is trying to help us stay open, they are giving us some latitude. So I just don't see a big help going there. But I wanted to follow up on one of the questions that has already been asked. What do you think the amount is for a bank to be too-big-to-fail? Or is there an amount? Mr. Bernanke. No. First of all, again, we are working again to get rid of too-big-to-fail, so any bank that fails would be subject to this Orderly Liquidation Authority. But in designating firms, for example, as systemically important, which is not the same as too-big-to-fail, we look at not just the size, but also the complexity, the interconnectedness to other banks, the kinds of activities they have and so on. So a simple dollar number is not really adequate to describe whether a bank is systemically critical or not. Mr. Westmoreland. I hope that as we continue to talk about too-big-to-fail, we will also look at the banks that are too- small-to-save. I yield back. Mr. Campbell. The gentleman yields back. The gentlelady from Wisconsin, Ms. Moore, is recognized for 5 minutes. Ms. Moore. Thank you so much, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for appearing today and tolerating this long testimony. I have a couple of questions for you. One of the consequences of our almost defaulting on our debt and the whole debt crisis, raising the debt limit, was we saw a lot of chatter around the world about abandoning the U.S. dollar as a reserve currency, and I am wondering what your outlook is on the economic growth or contraction of our economy were that to occur, that we would lose our status, that the U.S. dollar would lose the status of a reserve currency? Mr. Bernanke. Let me say first that I don't see any sign that is happening. The amount of reserves held in dollars is actually growing, not shrinking. So I think that reserve currency status at least for the foreseeable future is very much intact. If we lost that, it would probably have some effect on the interest rates that we pay because we would have fewer holders for our bonds and that in turn might have some impact on our economy. But, again, I don't think that this is a very likely prospect in the foreseeable future. Ms. Moore. Why did we have all the chatter about it, with the larger economies, Latin America, China? Mr. Bernanke. Of course, the world is evolving. The Chinese would like their currency at some point to become a reserve currency. There is some distance for them to go before they can get to that point. But, as I said, at least in the near term, pretty close to two-thirds of all global reserves are held in dollars, and that doesn't seem to be changing very much. Ms. Moore. Thank you. Listen, I want to talk about too-big-to-fail as well, global too-big-to-fail, and I want to say that I was really pleased to see the FDIC and the European Commission working together to establish a legal framework to create a global system for unwinding large systemically important firms similar to our Orderly Liquidation Authority that we created in Dodd- Frank. Is there more that this committee and Congress can do towards this effort or other cross-border efforts? And I would be interested in hearing about other efforts that the Fed is undertaking to further coordinate global monetary policy, particularly with bank regulation standards, and anti-money laundering efforts. What other things are you doing? Mr. Bernanke. On an Orderly Liquidation Authority, as you mentioned the FDIC, which is leading this effort, has been working with European counterparts. They published a paper with the U.K. authorities, I believe it was a few months ago. The Fed has been working very closely with the FDIC. Recently, for example, I attended a table top exercise where we pretended that there was a bank failing and asked ourselves what we would do under the laws that Orderly Liquidation Authority provides. The Financial Stability Board, which is an international body of regulators, and other international bodies like the Basel Committee and so on, have been discussing the issues related to international banks and how they might be liquidated in a crisis. That is the most difficult issue, I think, that we still have to work on. But we are making progress, and there is a lot of international interest in finding ways to work together to deal with the institution which crosses many borders. More generally, the level of international cooperation in regulatory matters is quite high. There are a number of international bodies. The U.S., the U.K. and the other major banking centers cooperate quite extensively on these issues. The CFTC and the SEC are working on derivatives issues. So there is a lot of work going on. On monetary policy, we exchange ideas and discuss the economy quite frequently in different settings, but we don't directly coordinate monetary policy in the sense that we agree as a general matter to take actions together or in some sequence. Ms. Moore. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My time is limited so I just want to make a comment. You may not have time to respond to it. I did notice in your testimony that you noted that all taxing and spending decisions that Congress makes, and I know you don't like to comment on what we do, but that they are not equal. So, for example, lowering taxes on the wealthy does not necessarily have the same impact on our economy as giving unemployment benefits to the unemployed. Yes or no? Mr. Bernanke. Different taxes and different spending have different implications. Ms. Moore. Right. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentlelady from Minnesota, Mrs. Bachmann, for 5 minutes. Mrs. Bachmann. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here today. I was reading your testimony, and I thank you for giving it, especially on pages 7 and 8. On page 7, you talked about the sequestration and the impact of the sequestration and your concerns about that impact currently on the short term and the economic drag that could bring about. Then on page 8, you talked about the fact that at some point down the road we have to deal with our current debt and our current overspending. You had also said in your comments before us that we need to align our solutions with the problem, meaning I take it that the spending reductions shouldn't happen today, they should wait until tomorrow when we really start to have problems. So is that how you would quantify that, yes or no? Mr. Bernanke. I didn't say we have to get rid of the spending cuts today, but just more gradual introduction combined with longer-term measures. Mrs. Bachmann. So let me ask you--some very quick kind of technical answers is what I am looking for. What was the United States' deficit last year? Mr. Bernanke. I have it right here. It was $1.09 trillion. Mrs. Bachmann. $1.09 trillion. And what was our total national debt for last year, or currently? Mr. Bernanke. About $11 trillion. Mrs. Bachmann. And what is our current total national debt this year? Mr. Bernanke. It is currently, I think, about $11.5 trillion. Mrs. Bachmann. Not 16.5 trillion? Mr. Bernanke. The $16 trillion includes intra-governmental debt like the Social Security Trust Fund. But debt held by the public as opposed to debt held between different parts of the government is about $11.5 trillion. Mrs. Bachmann. So you are saying the debt is about $11.5 trillion. And what are the unfunded net liabilities? Mr. Bernanke. They are very large, particularly in the Medicare area. I don't have a number, but they are probably some greater than the actual official debt held by the public. Mrs. Bachmann. And how much debt do we buy every day from the Treasury, from the Federal Reserve? Mr. Bernanke. Every day? About $1.5 billion? Mrs. Bachmann. About $1.5 billion. So without the Fed purchases of our debt from the Treasury, would we be able to continue the spending level? Mr. Bernanke. Yes, you could. As I said before, the Fed only owns about 15 percent of the outstanding U.S. Government debt. Mrs. Bachmann. Where would we go? If we didn't have the Fed buying that debt, where would we go? Mr. Bernanke. Our debt is in great demand. Foreigners hold about half of it. People think of U.S. Treasury debt as a safe haven and as a secure investment. That is why, notwithstanding what the Fed is doing, we can sell it at low interest rates. Mrs. Bachmann. So the Fed wouldn't need to be buying all these Treasuries then, we could find other buyers for our debt, is that true? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mrs. Bachmann. So then why are we doing it? Mr. Bernanke. To keep rates a little bit lower, to help support housing, automobiles, and other parts of the economy that need more support. Mrs. Bachmann. But if there are other buyers, why the Fed? Mr. Bernanke. To get rates a little bit lower than they otherwise would be. Mrs. Bachmann. So if my 18-year-old daughter was spending 40 percent more than what my husband and I were giving her, and she didn't do that just this month, but she did it next month and the next month and the next month, and finally my husband and I said we are just not going to bail you out anymore, we are just not going to continue to finance the overspending that you are doing, and she said to me, mother, we need to align our solution with the problem, in other words, you need to keep giving me that money because it is really not a problem yet. I would say I think you have a problem today. And the reason why I would say that is because the analogy with the Federal Government, in January of 2007 our debt was $8.67 trillion. That debt today is closer to $16.5 trillion, with the intra- government debts, according to your calculation. Do you think that is a problem, that in 6 years we have gone from $8.67 trillion to $16.5 trillion? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly that is a problem, and that is why I think it is important to have measures to bring it down over time. Mrs. Bachmann. But you said we need to align the solution with the problem. It seems to me we have a big problem, and I will tell you why. When I was home last week and talking to a lot of women, they were telling me, ``I don't get this. Gasoline at Christmastime was $2.99 a gallon. Now, it is $4 a gallon.'' They said, ``I can't keep up with the price increases at the grocery store. And we just got our health insurance premium and it is going to be $300 a month more than what it was.'' So all I want to say, Mr. Chairman, is that what I am hearing from the people is that they are having to deal with the inflationary problem. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentlelady has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Texas, Mr. Hinojosa, for 5 minutes. Mr. Hinojosa. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Bernanke, thank you for coming to visit with our committee and thank you for your leadership and for your foresight in the handling of our fiscal policy. Your testimony comes at a pivotal time in our Nation's Capital. While we want to address the long-term health of the Federal balance sheet, the sequester cuts are so drastic and so immediate that they greatly threaten economic growth. In your remarks, you suggest Congress consider a longer-term horizon for targeted fiscal changes, and I completely agree with you. The sequester is totally unnecessary and illustrates a lack of political courage by Members of Congress. We have spent a lot of time in this committee attempting to reduce uncertainty in the economy. We have done it by reducing uncertainty for banks, by finalizing rules, and we have done it by reducing uncertainty for small businesses by encouraging lending. Uncertainty around effects of the sequester is no doubt already chilling the economy and confusion over the continuance of quantitative easing also creates uncertainty. For example, when word spread on Wall Street that the Federal Open Market Committee was considering ending or altering QE3, the Dow Jones dropped significantly. We cannot throw more uncertainty into such a fragile economy and have consumer confidence erode. Many of my friends across the aisle will argue that current fiscal policy is causing the economy to overheat. At the same time, all of us are concerned about still too high unemployment. How can a so-called overheating economy see employment grow so slowly? And furthermore, Chairman Bernanke, I would like to ask you, do you think that our economy is indeed overheating, and can you give us a sense of where the economy would be had you not implemented quantitative easing? Also discuss with us the impact of a sudden fiscal contraction on economic uncertainty, and ultimately tell us about the recovery that you foresee. Mr. Bernanke. I don't think the economy is overheating. There still seems to be quite a bit of unused resources, a lot of people out of work who could be working, capital that could be used that is not being used. So, again, I don't see any overheating. We believe that the monetary policies that we have conducted have helped get stronger recovery and more jobs than we otherwise would have had. There have been different studies that give different numbers, but most of them do find a pretty significant effect. On the fiscal side, as I mentioned, the CBO attributes to the sequester about six-tenths of a percentage point of growth in 2013 which they connect to the full-time equivalent of about 750,000 jobs. So from the CBO's perspective, there is an important job component or job effect arising from fiscal contraction which, again, as I have said many times, the Federal Reserve really can't overcome. We don't really have tools sufficiently powerful to overcome the impact of those types of fiscal actions. Mr. Hinojosa. Do you believe that the sequester kicking in on Friday would lead the markets to tumble? Mr. Bernanke. The markets already know about the sequester. It isn't news to them. So I don't think necessarily that the markets will respond to the beginning of the sequester. But, again, I think a good policy, one that would be good for the economy and probably good for markets, would be one that, again, takes a longer-term perspective and takes some significant steps to address our longer-term fiscal imbalances while phasing in more slowly some of the changes occurring at the present time. Mr. Hinojosa. I ask that question because I spoke to a lot of teachers, a lot of people who have 401(k)s and saw what happened in 2008 when the markets tumbled about 40 percent and they lost so much equity, and they are concerned that might happen again. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from New Mexico, Mr. Pearce, for 5 minutes. Mr. Pearce. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here, and for your presentation today. I would like to echo what Mrs. Capito said about the energy economy, and the three counties in the southeast part of New Mexico where $100,000 jobs driving a truck are going wanting. The Occupy People say they don't have jobs, but they don't come out where they are. And they are good paying jobs. At my last job fair, we were trying to bring people and put them together with folks who were looking for workers, and 14 driving jobs in one company went without being filled, and 3,000 jobs at another job fair went wanting, and the Nation treats this like it is some sort of secondary effect. Nationwide, I would point out that the Bureau of Labor Statistics shows 3.6 million jobs are available right now in America, and yet we have 8 percent, 7.5 percent, whatever percent unemployment, and I think at some point, the country needs to deal with that. I would also like to echo what Mrs. Capito said about the seniors. Her seniors seem to be a little more gentle than mine. I just had a telephone town hall last night and Susan from Los Ninos and Leone from my district also were quite energized about the whole concept of quantitative easing. And I know that the price of gasoline and the price of groceries don't rise to the level of importance to where the Feds would actually measure those in the computations, but we are 47th per capita income, and when we are told that inflation is not going up at all, it is eating the lunch of our seniors who can't afford to fill their fuel tanks and buy groceries. Now, I would invite you to come and sit with me in an open town hall in New Mexico. Would you be open to that? We could contact your scheduler maybe. Mr. Bernanke. You can talk to the scheduler to see if it is possible. Mr. Pearce. I would take that as a very positive sign that you would be interested in talking to people on that end of the economic ladder. But they don't buy these explanations that quantitative easing is this great miracle that I am hearing today, but they understand the creation of money out of thin air depreciates what they have, and as always, inflation hurts the poor worse than anyone else, and that is our district. So Susan asked, would you put all your money--just so you get the full benefit of zero interest rates, why don't you put all of your money in savings accounts? Because many of these people are unsophisticated investors, like Chairman Garrett suggested. They are not comfortable. They don't know all these risky things. They see Wall Street and they see all the derivatives and all this jazz that got everybody hyped up and cost us several trillion dollars to pay back those people who took those risks, but they don't buy it. And they are furious with the government. They say, ``We lived our life right. We paid off our homes. We put money into the bank. We had a nest egg that was sufficient at the going rate of interest. And now our government is bragging that we have zero interest and we are being punished after living our lives correctly.'' My mom is in that category. She is 80- something; I hope that she doesn't go out and start finding a stock investor right now. So I think at some point it would be nice for you to get out among people who have manure on the bottom of their boots like we do in New Mexico. You spend a lot of time on page 7 quoting the CBO about the effects of the sequester. You even talked about it. But I was unsure if you agree with the CBO or if you simply are quoting the CBO. Are you in full agreement with the effects that you have put into your paper? Mr. Bernanke. Broadly speaking, yes. Mr. Pearce. Fairly speaking, I am wondering, you also say that there were temporary interruptions to the economy, the weather-related interruptions to the economy. That is page one of your testimony. I am seeing in the Financial Times that Wal- Mart and all the other retailers are worrying about that price increase or the payroll tax increase that was passed along at the end of last year as being maybe as big an effect. The cost is about the same, $95 billion more or less. And yet I don't find any reference, I don't find a reference to the penalizing effect that that tax increase had. Mr. Bernanke. I did mention that the overall effect of all the changes is about 1.5 percentage points, and that includes the payroll. Mr. Pearce. But you do mention the sequester. You use a little bit different language. You don't actually come out and say ``the sequester,'' but you do mention that our solutions are going to cause great headwinds, but you don't mention the headwinds from that other decision there to raise taxes. Mr. Bernanke. I did mention those, yes. Mr. Pearce. I find the omission very curious. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from North Carolina, Mr. Watt, for 5 minutes. Mr. Watt. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I thank Chairman Bernanke for being here. I apologize for being late. I was over in the Supreme Court listening to the arguments on the voting rights case. Sometimes, it is kind of difficult to be in two places at one time, I have found. I want to go back to the prior questioner because my constituents obviously are living in a slightly different world than his and are getting ready to live apparently in a more significantly different world than his unless we do something between now and Friday. We spent a lot of time in yesterday's hearing talking about the impact of sequestration, and it is really vexing a lot of people, although I confess that most people don't know what a sequester is. You say at the top of page 7 that monetary policy is working to promote a more robust recovery but it can't carry the entire burden of ensuring a speedier return to economic health. The economy's performance, both over the near term and in the longer run, will depend importantly on the course of fiscal policy. That is something which is under the Congress' control, as opposed to monetary policy, which is under the Fed's control. And you make some observations about the short- and long-term impact. I am wondering if you have some views about the impact, the likely impact, notwithstanding the monetary policies that the Fed has implemented, of sequester in the form that it is about to take effect if we don't do anything between now and Friday? Mr. Bernanke. I haven't made any comment about the specific allocation of cuts across different departments. Those are issues for the Congress to debate. What I did was cite the CBO numbers, which again I think are reasonable, which suggest that all of the fiscal measures, including the payroll tax increase, are equal to about 1.5 percentage points of drag this year, and that the sequester by itself is about six-tenths of drag according to the CBO and according to I think most standard analyses. Mr. Watt. And you said you generally agreed with the CBO's analysis of that? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Watt. All right. So you are saying that sequestration could have six-tenths of one percentage impact-- Mr. Bernanke. On the growth rate. It brings the growth rate down. Mr. Watt. On the growth rate. Okay. And in this kind of economy that is fragile, what would you project would be the consequences of that? Mr. Bernanke. The CBO suggests that the job impact in full time equivalents would be about 750,000. Mr. Watt. So that is 750,000 more people unemployed than would otherwise be. Mr. Bernanke. Than would otherwise be the case. Or an unemployment rate that might stay where it is or go up a little rather than coming down by the end of the year. Mr. Watt. And what about the uncertainty associated from a business and economic perspective? What would you project there? Mr. Bernanke. It is hard to measure the uncertainty effects, but there has been a whole sequence of events going back to the 2011 debt ceiling debate, and now we have had the fiscal cliff and sequester and all these things, and what we hear at least anecdotally from people around the country is that it does create uncertainty and makes it more difficult for them to plan, to hire, to invest. Mr. Watt. More difficult for them to hire and invest. I wanted to reemphasize that. So you think-- Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. Mr. Watt. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The chairman recognizes the gentleman from Pennsylvania, Mr. Fitzpatrick, for 5 minutes. Mr. Fitzpatrick. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Bernanke, thank you for your time and your insight here and your service to the people. When you were here last year, the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) indicated that the unemployment rate was higher than it is today. Today, I think the BLS is saying it is about 7.9 percent, although most people throughout the country believe it is much higher, including people in Bucks County, Pennsylvania, which I represent, especially among younger workers, especially recent graduates, just graduating from high school trying to get in the market. I spoke earlier today on the other side of the city to the American Legion about the increasing number of returning veterans from Afghanistan, and some believe that the unemployment rate among veterans is twice the national average, and, of course, all of this is unacceptable. So from 2001 to the present, our country has had a significant increase in population. We have increasing numbers of veterans coming home looking for work in a very difficult economy. Some are suggesting because there are fewer people working today than were working, employed today than were working in 2001, that our country may have just experienced a lost decade similar to what Japan went through in the 1990s and the 2000s. Do you agree with that? Are there any differences between what happened in Japan and what is happening here in our country, and if so, what policy suggestions would you make to address it? Mr. Bernanke. There obviously has been a very severe, difficult, economic period. I don't know about calling it a lost decade. There are important differences between the United States and Japan. Japan has an even more rapidly aging society than we do. Their workforce is actually declining. They have had more difficulties with their banking sector. We were more rapid in getting our banks up and running again, so to speak. And, very importantly, the Federal Reserve has kept inflation close to 2 percent and we have avoided deflation, which was the major problem for the Japanese. In terms of what to do about it, first of all, there are many things that could be done to address our long-run economic prosperity in terms of good tax policy, and good decisions about encouraging public and private infrastructure, things that I mentioned at the end of my testimony. In the short term, it is our view that there is still a good bit of slack in the economy, that we are not using all the resources we have. As you mentioned, we have very high unemployment in certain categories, and that is the basis both for the accommodative monetary policy that we have, keeping interests rates low and trying to stimulate housing and durable goods and so on, and also for the recommendation that fiscal policy go gradually as Congress tries to address the long-term deficit issues. Mr. Fitzpatrick. The Fed has indicated that it believes in the long term, unemployment rates will settle at around 5.2 or 6 percent? Mr. Bernanke. That is our best guess. Mr. Fitzpatrick. I understand, and I heard testimony earlier about predicting the future, but when would you say we might get to around 6 percent? And also, the American people believe natural unemployment is actually much lower than that, given what we experienced in the 1990s, and maybe your suggestion as to how we address that expectation? Mr. Bernanke. Again, it is hard to predict, but a reasonable guess for 6 percent would be around 2016, about 3 more years. Mr. Fitzpatrick. In my remaining time, I just wanted to address the issue of the Fed's bond buying program. You said in your testimony last September that the FOMC announced it would purchase agency-backed mortgage securities at the pace of $40 billion per month, additionally $45 billion per month for Treasury securities. The FOMC has indicated it will continue purchases until it observes a substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market in the context of price stability. First of all, what would be the target improvement for the slowdown? Mr. Bernanke. We haven't given a specific number. We are looking for improvements in terms of employment, in terms of unemployment, in terms of a stronger economy that can deliver more jobs. The reason we haven't given a specific number, besides all the uncertainties involved, is that we are also looking at the efficacy and costs as I have described in my testimony. If all else is equal, if there are costs being generated by this policy that are concerning, that would, all else equal, make us do less. If it is more efficacious, then we might do more. Mr. Fitzpatrick. In my remaining 20 seconds, can you give us what a proposed strategy would be for the acquired positions that the Fed has right now, sales strategy? Mr. Bernanke. For the assets? Mr. Fitzpatrick. For the assets, right. Mr. Bernanke. We have been clear that at the time we decide to begin sales, we will give plenty of notice and proceed slowly and do so in a way consistent with our macro objectives. Mr. Fitzpatrick. I thank the chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Connecticut, Mr. Himes, for 5 minutes. Mr. Himes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, let me add my voice to those who have complimented you and thank you for your efforts over the last years to restore our economy to vitality. I suspect that when the history books are written, we will look at the twin engines of monetary and fiscal policy in this country and you will emerge as somebody who acted wisely and in good faith, and those of us charged with fiscal policy certainly in the last 2 years will be regarded at best as having dithered and at worst as having acted counterproductively to economic recovery. And I appreciate that throughout your testimony as well as throughout this report, you warn us of the dangers of premature sizable fiscal contraction, something which I have heard from the other side of the aisle over the course of the last 2 years is regarded by them as essential to our recovery. We have a theoretical discussion about that around Keynesianism and this and that. I do want to ask you a question though. In this report on monetary policy, you talk about the Euro area, and the report reads, ``The Euro area fell further into recession as fiscal austerity and other things led it a reduction in spending.'' To take this discussion out of the theoretical, any number of countries in the Euro area, Ireland, the U.K., Italy, Spain, pursued fiscal policies significantly more contractionary than our own. I wonder as you contemplate the Euro area, and here we are looking at sort of a real-time experiment and policy response, is there any country in the Euro area that pursued more aggressively contractionary fiscal policies than our own that has seen economic expansion, job creation, and meaningful reduction in debt to GDP? Mr. Bernanke. I don't think so. Mr. Himes. So there is really no country that has pursued the kind of austerity policies that we have heard some in this institution call for that have experienced economic growth or a reduction in the debt to their economy? Mr. Bernanke. I think Germany has had the best experience, but even there they have had a shrinking economy recently. Mr. Himes. Thank you. I appreciate that answer. To change topics here, I was very interested in the exchange that you had in the Senate, I believe yesterday, on the topic of Dodd-Frank. Senator Crapo, I think, asked to you reflect on what elements of that legislation you thought were good and perhaps which elements could stand improvement or that this institution should perhaps revisit, and I think you specifically highlighted Section 716 as an area that you thought perhaps we could revisit. I wonder, could you elaborate a little bit on Section 716, but also I would love to have you extend that discussion just based on what you have done in the last couple of years. What other areas do you think perhaps we may have gotten wrong or where perhaps we are experiencing unintended consequences or have created problems for the regulators in terms of implementation? Mr. Bernanke. Section 716 requires the push-out of certain kinds of derivatives, which means that banks can't manage those derivatives, they have to be in a separate company, a separate affiliate, and it is not evident why that makes the company as a whole safer. What we do see is that it will likely increase costs of people who use the derivatives and make it more difficult for the bank to compete with foreign competitors who can provide a more complete set of services. So there are some concerns about that particular rule. I think more generally though we want to ask the question, can we achieve the same objectives more efficiently, and more cheaply, and I think a review of some of the different elements would be useful. A number of people have mentioned concerns about community banks and small institutions, and I think an inventory, a broad inventory of the regulations affecting small banks would be worth doing in order to try to assess whether there are places where we can simplify and reduce the burden for those banks. Mr. Himes. Thanks. That is helpful. Would you be willing to comment in this context, Dodd-Frank and its subsequent regulatory implementation, how you think about the extent to which the broader too-big-to-fail problem has been addressed and are there areas where you think we could do better or differently? Mr. Bernanke. Dodd-Frank has a pretty comprehensive strategy for addressing too-big-to-fail. I think it is too early to say. I think we have made some progress, but I think it is too early to make a definitive conclusion because many of the relevant regulations are not even in effect yet. But, again, I think there is a strategy here and I think we ought to continue to pursue it and see how it shakes out. If it doesn't achieve the objective of eliminating too-big-to-fail, I think we ought to come back and decide or ask Congress whether they might take additional steps. Mr. Himes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. As a process point, the chairman will be the bearer of bad news to some Members on our current schedule. To respect the Chairman's schedule, it is likely that Representatives Luetkemeyer, Carney, Huizenga, and Kildee will likely be the last Members to be able to ask questions. At this point, the Chair will recognize Mr. Luetkemeyer of Missouri for 5 minutes. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for being here and enduring 3 hours of this again. I have some concerns with regards to the way we are going with quantitative easing from the standpoint that even in your own report here you talk about Japan, you talk about England, and you talk about China. All three have used quantitative easing and yet all three of them have, even in your own document here, their growth has continued to go the wrong direction. And I am curious about that. Even in The Wall Street Journal yesterday, it said that China now has it its own debt bomb. And one of the statements that it made in there is that through 2007, creating a dollar of economic growth in China required just over a dollar of debt. Since then, it is now taking $3 of debt to generate a dollar's worth of growth. This is what you normally see in the late stages of a credit binge as more debt goes into increasing less productive investments. So I guess my question is, while we are heading down the same path as these other countries, and my neighbor here, my friend to the left a while ago mentioned about Japan and their 20 years of trying this quantitative easing and now they have a stagnant economy, they have weak industries, they have little growth, and yet they have 200 percent of debt to GDP. We are headed down that same road, and obviously even your own documentation shows it is questionable whether it even works. What would be your response? Mr. Bernanke. I think the evidence for the United States is that while it is not incredibly powerful that it does work, we have seen a recovery that is not as fast as we would like, but it is nevertheless stronger and more meaningful than many other industrial countries. One way of interpreting Japan on the monetary side is that they were too cautious in that one of the most salient facts about Japan is that they have had deflation, falling prices now for quite a few years, and that is suggestive of a monetary policy which is not achieving price stability. And, as you know, the new prime minister and new governor of the Bank of Japan are promising more aggressive policies to try to eliminate deflation. So you could look at that either way. It is a problem for us that our normal short-term interest rate policies are no longer available because short rates are close to zero and so we have had to go to different methods as I described. But, again, our best estimates suggest that it has had a meaningful beneficial effect, and I have tried to be completely frank with this committee and talk about the downside as well because I would like you to understand the kind of cost-benefit analysis that we are doing. Mr. Luetkemeyer. I have some concerns from the standpoint that I don't know that we are doing things differently than other countries here, but hopefully you feel that we do. The other thing is you mentioned an exit strategy, and I understood what you were saying a while ago when you were talking about how there are different ways of going about it. Has any other country ever done this, had this large increase in the central bank's portfolio and then unwound it so that we know that this is a tested strategy that would work? Mr. Bernanke. Not in a precisely analogous way, because Japan, after all, which is really the only other country prior to the crisis which had used quantitative easing is still in that situation. But the tools that we are using or propose to use, such as the interest on reserves, for example, or the draining of reserve tools that we have, those have been used quite frequently by other central banks and they seem to work in their context. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Okay, one more quick question here before my time runs out, and it is with regards to a statement or comment you made in your opening statement, that the Federal Reserve is responding accurately to the financial stability concerns throughout substantially expanded monitoring of emerging risks in the financial system and approach to the supervision of financial firms that takes a more systemic perspective and the ongoing implementation of reforms to make the financial system more transparent and resilient. Can you give me some examples of things that you are doing with regards to systemic supervision, implementation of reforms, give me some specific examples? Mr. Bernanke. Sure. On the monitoring, we have greatly increased resources just to monitor all the different sectors of the financial markets. Both the Fed and the Financial Stability Oversight Council are doing that. In terms of macro-potential oversight, one good example is the stress testing that we now do, where we ask the largest banks to figure out what would happen to their capital if there was a very severe downturn in the economy and a very big decline in financial-- Mr. Luetkemeyer. Let me interrupt for one second. I am running out of time here. Can you give me examples of reforms to make the system more transparent and resilient? Mr. Bernanke. The Basel rules, for example, require more disclosure. Our stress tests, we publish the results so that the markets know what the results are for each individual bank. Mr. Luetkemeyer. Thank you very much. My time has expired. Thank you very much for your answers. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has indeed expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Delaware, Mr. Carney, for 5 minutes. Mr. Carney. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you, Chairman Bernanke, for your testimony today, for your report, and really for your great leadership on monetary policy for our country over the last several years. I think you are the right person at the right time for what we needed. And you have given us, frankly, great advice. We haven't really followed it with respect to smart fiscal policy. We appreciate your comments on that. You have consistently said that we need to be careful in the short term, do no harm in the short term, if I may, and address our long-term imbalances, fiscal imbalances in the outyears. In your testimony, you say specifically that the Federal deficit and debt as a percentage of GDP will begin rising again in the latter part of this decade, reflecting in large part the aging of the population and fast rising health care costs. Do you believe as I do that health care costs are the primary driver of our outyear deficits? Mr. Bernanke. They are. Yes. Mr. Carney. From our perspective, we have Medicare, Medicaid, Federal employees, military health care. What should be our goal? What we should be focusing on? Have you thought much about this as it relates to what the country needs to do with these fiscal challenges? Mr. Bernanke. As you know, health care is a very complicated subject and nobody has a single answer. I think one way of describing our problem is we have fee-for-service and third-party pay together, which means that doctors can order as many tests as they want and the patient doesn't care because they know somebody else will pay for it. There are many different ways to address that. One way is to have the consumer bear some of the financial costs. Another way is to have tighter controls from the government which is paying the cost. So there are many different approaches. Certainly, we want to be rewarding doctors and hospitals for quality. We want to have more transparency about their processes. Mr. Carney. How about health care as a sector? Should we be looking at--we have these debates in my State of Delaware all the time about somebody is expanding and building a new hospital right down the street from where I live, a new surgery center put here. And we talk a lot about economic development. I think you could also see it as frankly an increase in overhead. Those costs are going to be borne by somebody, and they are either employers or the government it seems to me. How would an economist look at that in terms of the health care sector writ large and health care employment? Mr. Bernanke. That is exactly right. We have scarce resources. We don't have infinite amounts of money to spend on health care. We want to deploy it in ways that have the greatest benefit for the least cost, and there are different ways to go about doing that. But clearly, getting the per capita cost of health care under control would not only be very good for the Federal budget, but it would be a terrific thing for our economy more broadly because, of course, individuals and companies also pay health care costs. Mr. Carney. So you may not want to comment on this, but one of the specific ideas that have been floated is to increase the age for Medicare eligibility, which doesn't do anything for the cost of the people who have that. As I see it, it just shifts that cost from the government frankly or from that system to the private sector or private payors. Do you have any thoughts on that generally? Mr. Bernanke. It relates to what I just said, which is this is not just a Federal fiscal problem, it is an economy-wide problem, and so the real solutions, the real lasting solutions will involve changing the way we pay doctors and hospitals so that they will have the incentives to keep costs under control, whether it is the government paying it or whether it is a private sector person paying it. Mr. Carney. Thank you. One last question. You mentioned earlier when we were talking about too-big-to-fail with Representative Capuano that you no longer, under Dodd-Frank, have the tools that were available to you in 2008. Do you need additional tools? There has been a lot of discussion among people that I have talked to about in addition maybe to Orderly Liquidation Authority, which I guess a district judge would order having some sort of enhanced financial bankruptcy, that might be an option as well. Do you have any thoughts on additional tools? Mr. Bernanke. No, we are not asking for any additional tools at this juncture. We continue to work on the Orderly Liquidation Authority with the FDIC, and at some point it would be a good idea for Congress to review that process and see if you are comfortable with the approach that the FDIC in particular has suggested for dealing with a failing firm. Mr. Carney. Thank you, Chairman Bernanke. I yield back. Chairman Hensarling. The Chair recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Huizenga, for 5 minutes. Mr. Huizenga. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate that. Chairman Bernanke, I appreciate you being here as well. I am going to try to move quickly and express some opinions, but I also have a couple of questions, and I too want to sort of log my caution on what we have been doing with our monetary policy and the easing that we have had. There has been lots of discussion about this economy being very fragile, I have heard a number of my friends and colleagues over there, and why we ``can't allow the across-the- board cuts to go in place.'' But it seems to me that no one is really commenting on the tax increases proposed by the White House or the increased regulation that we are seeing, whether it is through the EPA, certainly through Dodd-Frank that this committee is dealing with, et cetera, et cetera. As one of my business owners back home put it to me, he said, ``Look, it is not like this one little piece, this one grain of sand, is going to stop the machine. But when you start adding 10 or 20 or 30 or 40 or 50 and then you start pounding it in with a mallet, suddenly that little grain of sand does start grinding on that machine and it breaks it down.'' I think that is exactly what we have seen with much of the regulation. But in addition to that, we haven't talked about the hit from the tax rate lapses, the so-called Bush/Obama tax rates that were there, and I would like to see my friends have a greater conversation about that. At the time, Ernst & Young put out a study that letting tax rates for the wealthiest Americans lapse would cost about 700,000 jobs, the exact same numbers basically, and I am not trying to compare apples and oranges. I think as one wise person said, we might be talking about red apples versus green apples here. But we have to look at that side of the equation as we are moving forward. The long term, I want to talk a little bit about that, and I have a specific question. On page 5, to quote your report today, ``However, the committee remains--the committee being you all--confident that it has the tools necessary to tighten monetary policy when the time comes to do so,'' and I know you have laid out 2015, 2016, that timeframe. Exactly what tools do you believe that you are going to employ to put that restraint back in place? Mr. Bernanke. We earlier discussed the exit sequence. So, first, we can simply allow securities on our balance sheet to run off and not replace them as we currently are doing. Second, we have a number of tools that can be used to drain reserves from the system, such as reverse repos. Third, we can raise interest rates even without reducing our balance sheet by raising the interest rate we pay on excess reserves which will in turn translate into higher interest rates in money markets. And fourth and finally, and it is not the first resort, but eventually we can sell the securities back into the market in a slow predictable way. Mr. Huizenga. This has not been done though, I think as we talked about with Japan and others, correct? This is the theory of how we are going to do this. Mr. Bernanke. Each of the elements is something that we have tested, that we have seen other countries use, so we think we understand it pretty well. Mr. Huizenga. So the thing I did appreciate is you laid out three things that you wanted to have brought to light today, and interest rates won't be this low forever was something I think we were not living with the reality of or the recognition of that. I am curious, because you talk about there, and I am afraid that the headlines tomorrow are going to be, ``Bernanke blasts across-the-board cuts,'' and/or, ``Bernanke calls for a stoppage of the across-the-board cuts,'' when frankly, based on what I read and what I have heard of the testimony today, I think the headlines ought to be, ``Bernanke calls for long-term reforms.'' And there is just a denial in this town in so many ways about what is happening now and in the future. What would you say to those who say we can't or shouldn't reform these long-term programs? Mr. Bernanke. I don't think we have any choice. I think I have tried throughout this discussion to always have two parts to the recommendation. Mr. Huizenga. You are a good economist. One hand or the other hand. Mr. Bernanke. I have a third hand here, too. Anyway, with the idea being that we want to reduce somewhat the fiscal drag in 2013. And I am not speaking only about the sequester. I talked about all of the fiscal actions which collectively are about 1.5 percentage points, according to the CBO. But I am not here to recommend that we just kick the can indefinitely down the road. I still think it is very important to address the long-range issues. Mr. Huizenga. We have about 10 seconds. So this is Medicare, Medicaid, Social Security reform? Mr. Bernanke. The specifics are up to Congress, but obviously-- Mr. Huizenga. Those are our long-term drivers of that. So there you go, folks. The headline for tomorrow is, ``Bernanke calls for long-term fixes.'' Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. The Chair now recognizes the gentleman from Michigan, Mr. Kildee, for 5 minutes. Mr. Kildee. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and in respect for the time that Chairman Bernanke has provided us, I will ask one I think very important question, and then if allowable, yield the remainder of my time to my colleague, Mr. Ellison, to ask a question. Before I came to Congress, as I mentioned to you before the hearing, I was in local government. I was the county treasurer of Genesee County, Michigan, which is home to Flint, Michigan. We have seen recently over the last couple of years, but even in the last few weeks, a significant number of downgrades to municipal debt which by itself is an issue that I am interested in your thinking on, but I think also represents a symptom of a much larger problem, and that is municipal insolvency generally. We have seen Vallejo, California; Harrisburg, Pennsylvania; Camden, New Jersey; my own hometown of Flint, Michigan, and now we see Detroit facing this insolvency. The solutions, the State-based solutions to these problems typically have been replacing existing management with different management that can presumably make different decisions that result in outcomes that are more favorable. I think what we are facing, in my opinion, in my work across the country, is something much bigger than a failure of management but a structural failure in what I think is potentially another institutional failure in the urban setting, in municipal governments. I am interested in your thoughts about the implications for that trend, if you agree that it is taking place on our economy, what solutions the Federal Government might consider, if any, to deal with that. And then a corollary to that, to the extent that the sequester will disproportionately affect the most vulnerable of our citizens, isn't it also logical to assume that the sequester cuts might exacerbate what is already a growing problem in urban America and make this insolvency even more difficult to manage? Mr. Bernanke. The last few years have been a very tough time for State and local governments. Not only are income and sales taxes down, but so are property taxes as property values have come down as well. As a result, as I mentioned before, State and local governments have cut workforces, have cut spending, have cut capital projects. Some have been able to steady the ship. Others are still under a lot of stress. Obviously, in the short term trying to promote job creation as the Fed is trying to do and as I am asking the Congress to think about in their decisions is going to help a lot of these areas by creating more economic activity and more tax revenues. There are obviously some parts of the country where there are longer-term, more structural problems that are not just business cycle problems, and some of those may be in your State. There I don't really have a solution. The Federal Government has not in the past involved itself that much with those distressed municipalities. Mr. Kildee. I guess if I could just quickly follow up on that, the Federal Government hadn't involved themselves in a lot of things until the necessity appeared. What I am concerned about the State governments may not have the capacity and the cities failing will be a national problem one way or another. I suggest perhaps at a different juncture we might pursue some thought about how the Federal Government might intervene in that case. I would yield the remainder of my time to Mr. Ellison. Mr. Ellison. Thank you, Mr. Kildee. I am very grateful. Chairman Bernanke, I don't have much time so I am going to ask you straight, Sheila Bair had an article in today's New York Times focusing on income inequality. My question to you is, does inequality matter in terms of the inefficiency and functioning and growth of our economy? Mr. Bernanke. It is very important in its own right. We want everybody to have opportunities, we want a fair society. I think it does. If people don't have--if talented people don't have the ability to move up and get a good education and to move into the middle class, that that is a loss for everyone, not just for those individuals. So I think a society in which there is greater equality of opportunity will be a more productive and efficient society as well. Mr. Ellison. Those points you made I think are absolutely right, but 70 percent of our economy is consumer spending. If folks on the bottom don't have-- Mr. Bernanke. But in the longer term, what matters is our productive capacity. And there, human talent and skills are really the most important thing. In this country, we had a period where we brought women into the labor force, and that brought a whole new set of skills and talents into our economy. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired just under the wire. The last word will go to the gentleman from Wisconsin. Mr. Duffy is recognized for 5 minutes. Mr. Duffy. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And good afternoon, Chairman Bernanke. Yesterday in the Senate hearing, you had a conversation about some of your concerns about Dodd-Frank. You didn't have much time to answer that question. Would you mind sending me in writing a little more detail on all of your concerns with Dodd-Frank, maybe, say, in 2 weeks? Mr. Bernanke. Sure. But we don't have a long list of specifics at this point. Mr. Duffy. That is okay. Mr. Bernanke. I do think it would be a good thing for Congress to review. Mr. Duffy. But if you wouldn't mind sending the Fed's concerns, I would appreciate that. Is that okay? Mr. Bernanke. Certainly. Mr. Duffy. In 2 weeks? Mr. Bernanke. That would be fine. Mr. Duffy. 2 or 3 weeks? Mr. Bernanke. As soon as we can. Mr. Duffy. You have a big team. All right. Quickly, I want to talk about the debt. Roughly, we spend about, what, $225 billion a year to service our $16.5 trillion in debt. Is that right? Roughly? Mr. Bernanke. Sounds about right. Mr. Duffy. Okay. And for the CBO, for every additional point that our interest rates go up, it costs us an additional $100 billion a year to service the debt. Does that sound right? Mr. Bernanke. Yes. Mr. Duffy. So if you stop with your accommodative monetary policy, we could see interest rates rise 2 or 3 percent, right? So we would have an additional $200 billion to $300 billion of additional dollars going to service our current debt. Is that fair to say? Mr. Bernanke. That is right. CBO takes this into account in their projections. Mr. Duffy. And so, for me, I look at that and say, listen, this is a half a trillion dollars a year to service our current debt, $5 trillion over 10 years. I look at this and I see the lights going off, the sirens are blaring, and I am almost setting a proverbial can on my counter and you are kicking it saying, listen, don't worry about $85 billion in cuts; do it a different day. I listened to what you are saying, and I think you are giving cover to a set of policies that aren't responsible, and we are all going to pay the price for the fiscal irresponsibility. And instead of encouraging responsibility, you come in and say, listen, to cut 2 percent of our budget, you can't do it. It is going to have a great impact on our economy. Mr. Chairman, that doesn't make sense to me. Mr. Bernanke. I think most economists, including the CBO, would say that this will cost a lot of jobs in the short run, and you can address--you can achieve the same results with longer-term programs. Mr. Duffy. And so on that point, how many jobs are lost if we cut the $27 million that go to Moroccan pottery classes or the $2.2 billion in free cell phones? We pay $700 billion to see how long shrimp can run on a treadmill. I believe we paid for the travel expenses for the Watermelon Queen in Alabama. There is fat in the budget, and I think every American looks at how we spend our money and they say, I can cut 2 percent out of my family budget, small businesses can say, I can cut 2 percent out of my budget, but you come in and tell us, listen, I agree with the President. It is catastrophic, it is catastrophic if you cut 2 percent, mass mayhem in our economy, I find that to be unbelievable. Mr. Bernanke. The sequester is not designed to cut wasteful stuff. It is across-the-board. Mr. Duffy. So, then, are you here telling us that if we cut $85 billion in a more reflective way in the bad spending that I just referenced, you would support it? It is a good idea if we are not doing it by way of the sequester, but we have a little more reflective analysis-- Mr. Bernanke. It would be better. Mr. Duffy. --on the $85 billion? Mr. Bernanke. It would be better. Mr. Duffy. So is it better, or you would agree with us that we should actually reduce spending? Mr. Bernanke. I am still concerned about the short-run impact on jobs. And you don't get as much benefit as you think, because if you slow the economy, that hurts your revenues, and that means your deficit reduction is not as big as you think it is. Mr. Duffy. So the revenues that we get from the Moroccan pottery classes, then, and the $2.2 billion in free cell phones, and the list goes on, Mr. Chairman, that is a great driver of economic growth in our country? Is that your position? Mr. Bernanke. Most of the spending goes to the military and to transfer programs like Social Security and Medicare. Mr. Duffy. And there is a lot of fat and you can find 2 percent fat that doesn't affect our military, doesn't affect our-- Mr. Bernanke. I also said in my testimony that not all spending and taxes are the same. I very much advocate trying to make good decisions about how you tax and how you spend. Mr. Duffy. So you agree there is fat and that you would encourage us to cut the fat, because if you weren't interjecting your policy, this would be a half a trillion dollar expense to the American Government, almost what we spend on our military? Mr. Bernanke. I think there is good--yes. It is obviously a good idea to improve or fiscal budgeting and to make better decisions, certainly. Mr. Duffy. I know you like to say you stick to monetary policy, but you do come in here and you talk about fiscal policy all the time. And if you don't like our approach to try and reduce how much we spend and you want to kick the can down the road, if--and I don't have much time, 15 seconds--if you wouldn't mind supplying in writing your plan for a long-term fiscal approach, I would appreciate that, because you keep-- whenever we try to cut spending, you come at us and say, don't cut spending today. No, no, no. Cut it tomorrow. If you have a better plan on how we can have a long-term approach to fix this problem, if you would submit that in writing, too, I would appreciate it, Mr. Chairman. Thank you. Mr. Bernanke. You bet. Chairman Hensarling. The time of the gentleman has expired. I would like to thank Chairman Bernanke for his testimony today. The Chair notes that some Members may have additional questions for this witness, which they may wish to submit in writing. Without objection, the hearing record will remain open for 5 legislative days for Members to submit written questions to this witness and to place his responses in the record. We would ask you, Chairman Bernanke, to please respond as promptly as you are able. Also, without objection, Members will have 5 legislative days to submit extraneous materials to the Chair for inclusion in the record. Without objection, the hearing is adjourned. [Whereupon, at 1:08 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.] A P P E N D I X February 27, 2013 [GRAPHIC(S) NOT AVAILABLE IN TIFF FORMAT]